liberals were the men of economie studies. Thornton, the mill-owner in North and South, is frequently using the common arguments of the economists, and the heroine of the novel therefore very appropriately addresses him as "an economist like you." 1 In Past and Present Carlyle reproaches the manufacturers that they defended the Iawless anarchy by which they profited. The novelists who in their books paid attention to the problems of the day—and most of them did so now and then, although few feit induced to write special social novels, like Disraeli and Mrs. Gaskell—naturally took sides with the humanitarians, and for various reasons. In the first place it may be said in general that art and business are two spheres of life which represent its extremes, the one only concerned with idealism, and the other chiefly with materialism. And in Early Victorian times the gulf between them was perhaps wider than ever. A contemporary English writer considered that one of the prevalent causes Which obstructed the advancement of literature was "the common doctrine that we need in this country useful knowledge, rather than profound, extensive, elegant literature, and that this last, if we covet it, may be imported from abroad in such variety and abundance, as to save us the necessity of producing it ourselves." The author speaks of "utility work", and complains that "at the present moment English books want much which we need. The intellect of that nation is turned now to what are called useful and practical subjects." 2 Further the artistic mind of a writer of fiction is struck more forcibly by surrounding evils than those of most other persons: artists are highly sensitive to outward impressions, and are led by their feelings only, when reacting upon them. Greg was therefore quite right, when he spoke in this connection of two groups of men, the feelers and the thinkers? The fact that novelists were to be found in the humanitarian camp, while Benthamite Utilitarianism and Orthodox Economy found its most powerful supporters in commercial and industrial circles, had a great influence upon the manner in which the business world is 1) North and South, p. 114. 2) The Importance and Means of a National Literature, by William miery Channing, pp. 11, 12, 28. London, 1835. 3) W. R. Greg, op. cit., p. 177. 29 represented in fiction. It induced many novelists to draw portraits of merchants and manufacturers that were mere embodiments of the general mental attitude in the hostile camp. Another circumstance tending in the same direction was that, not knowing so much of practical business life and the daily work done in the counting-house and the mill, authors would consider it a very convenient method to endow their business people with all the qualities that were supposed to make up the utilitarian character. This led to the conception of a Benthamite business-man as a new literary type, which is found back with surprising regularity in many Early Victorian novels. Now the popular conception of the character of Benthamite Utilitarians and Orthodox Economists was not a flattering one. The first had long been regarded with great distrust by every respectable person, who feared to commit himself before 1832 by meddling with their schemes of reform, while every religious person shrank back from their rationalism. Even when about 1832 their political confederates, the Philosophical Radicals, succeeded in carrying many of their reforms through Parliament, other parties still regarded them with aversion. This is proved by a passage in John Stuart Mill's Autobiography, where he says that his father held opinions "both in politics and religion, which were more odious to all persons of influence, and to the common run of prosperous Englishmen in that generation, than either before or since." 1 Political economists enjoyed a reputation which was hardly better, as we shall see presently. It is not surprising to find, therefore, that, when novelists used this type of men as representatives of the trading middle classes, the result was not as a rule a very prepossessing portrait. The most elaborate of such literary portraits has been drawn by Mrs. Gaskell in the person of the mill-owner John Thornton, whom we have already mentioned on other occasions. The principal 1) Autobiography, p. 3. London, 1873. Punch, which in its early volumes is perhaps the truèst mirror of Early Victorian times that has come down to us, speaks of the Radicals in the same strain. "To be a radical, was,—in the early days of Radicalism, to be pariah—a foul vile thing—an ulcer in the body-social—a blotch to be extirpated by fire or knife." But by 1841 things had completely changed. The writer continues: "In due season coronets were waved to the goodly presence of Reform, and Radicalism was the synonym of patriotism. Vol. II, p. 210. 30 features of this person's character are found back again in most other business-men belonging to this type. They are chiefly: a cold rationalist view of his place in society and his relation to its other classes, which is of a purely economie nature, somewhat like the "cash nexus" of which Carlyle repeatedly speaks in Past and Present; a greatly exaggerated feeling of independence in the management of his affairs, sometimes leading to a kind of unfounded pig-headedness that is not very convincing to the reader—Thornton has taken measures to abate the smoke nuisance of his own free will, but would have refused to do so under compulsion—; a strong and indomitable will, when he is opposed or thwarted; a strong and clear faculty for going straight to the core of a question in a logical marnier; not so much unjust as unfeeling in his dealings with others, "reasoning as if commerce were everything, and humanity nothing;" possessing an innate hatred of scènes, and a great contempt for all people showing emotion, as in his eyes it betrayed a want of selfcontrol. John Thornton's mother is of the same stamp, and the usual talk between mother and son is "about facts, not opinions, far less feelings." Such a character description tallies in a wonderful way with what we read of the leaders of the utilitarian and economie school of thought. Of Bentham Leslie Stephen tells us that "he was always dealing with concrete facts, and a great part of his writings may be considered as raw material for acts of parliament ... he had not that knowledge which we ascribe either to the poet or to the man of the world. He had neither the passion, nor the sympathetic imagination. The springs of active conduct which Byron knew from actual experience, were to Bentham nothing more than names in a careful classification ... at eighty he had not found out of what men are really made." 1 Harriet Martineau, the author who used fiction as a medium for the diffusion of orthodox economie principles among the lower classes, tells us that at 11 she put a question to her brother about "the old difficulty of foreknowledge and freewill." At eigtheen she studied the Bible "incessantly and immensely" by getting hold of all commentaries and works of elucidation that she could lay hands 1) Leslie Stephen, The English Utilitarians, vol. I, p. 233. London, 1900. 31 to any impressions in others which do not further or impede his own purpose. On his return to England he sets about the management of the family estate in a manner which shows that he intends to run it on commercial lines, and next sets up as a Radical in the county, without consulting his mother, a proud Tory lady, in anything, and without caring greatly to know even what other people thihk of him. "He had the energetic will and muscle," the novelist says, "the self-confidence, the quick perception, and the narrow imagination which make what is admiringly called the practical mind." She further descrdbes him as a clever, frank and agreeable person, a good-natured egoist, unsentimental, unsympathetic, unspeculative.1 As a last instance of the qualities of a utilitarian economist embodied in a literary portrait we may cite that of Lord Marney in Sybil. It is true that Lord Marney did not belong to the mercantile middle classes—factories are enterprises for the canaille according to this noble lord,2—but still he possesses the unmistakable qualities of Bentham's cBsciples: cynical, devoid of sentiment, arrogant and selfish, literal, harsh, anti-ecclesiastical, a rationalist, and an economist are the epithets bestowed upon him. That Disraeli drew such a character, not in the person of a mill-owner, but as a landed proprietor, is a curious fact which requires some elucidation. A French critic8 cites this portrait as one of the proofs that Utilitarianism had even permeated the aristocracy of the period, but this does not seem to be a very strong proof for such a highly improbable fact. In our opinion there was a special inducement for the author of the political novel Sybil to draw this picture. His chief object in writing the book was to attack the stagnant, dormant, fox-hunting, do-nothing Tory nobility, as it was described by the scathing pen of Carlyle in Past and Present. He wished to arouse those pseudo Tories, as he called them,4 and to reform them for the purpose of carrying his Young-England ideals into practice. To show us how much this aristocracy needed to be reformed, and how great the evils were which' it tolerated, or even produced, he attributed to it, 1) Felix Holt, the Radical, chapters I, VIII 2) Sybil or the Two Nations, p. 154. 3) L. Cazamian, op. cit. 4) Sybil, p. 49. 33 not only the agricultural misery on the estate of Lord Marney, but also the industrial degradation in the mushroom town on the estate of Lord Mowbray. Here his zeal for Young England reforms led him astray, however, for Lord Mowbray, the chief owner of the land on which this industrial conglomeration has sprung into existence, can hardly be considered accountable for the state of affairs there. His only fault is that the factories have "trebled the vast rental" of the landlord, but he is in no way connected with the mills and their hands. These are left to the tender mercies of masters like "those villains Shuffle and Screw." Yet it is not those rapacious mill-owners that figure in the novel, but a Mr. Trafford, a model employer and in every respect the opposite of the type who considered "cash nexus" as the sole relation between man and man. "He feit that between employer and employed there should be other ties than the payment and receipt of wages," Disraeli tells us, with a distinct echo of Carlyle's words. From these facts it seems clear that it is the landed proprietary who are held responsible for all evils, agricultural and industrial alike, and not the new middle classes. This view of Disraeli's attitude is strikingly corroborated by the following passage in Sybil: «You—i.c, the English aristocracy—have of late years dexterously thrown some of the odium of your polity upon that middle class which you despise, and who are despicable only because they imitate you—i.e., in their treatment of their dependents—."1 In accordance with this standpoint the author was of course to a certain extent under the necessity of endowing a nobleman—Lord Marney—with the usual literary attributes of a Benthamite: cynicism, lack of sentiment, arrogance, harshness, anti-ecclesiastical tendencies, protection of Dissent, a knowledge of the doctrines of the economists, etc. One of the most prominent features of the Benthamite commercial classes we are discussing in this chapter is perhaps their selfish heartlessness and often cruelty, and their indifference to the great sufferings of their fellow-men. No doubt Early Victorian novelists could show some very good grounds for this general conception. In the first place we may point to the fact that there were a large number of self-made man among the rising middle classes, and it has 1) Sybil, or the Two Nations, p. 278. 34 been rightly observed that "many a self-made man worships his own maker." 1 As at all other periods of a great social upheaval, many new men were borne upwards by the great economie waves produced by the French wars and the industrial revolution. These men were of course sturdy workers and daring adventurers, seeking their success in the accumulation of money, and such men frequently make hard masters. Having succeeded in life themselves by hard work and unrelenting exertion, they were equally exacting for their dependents, and despised their weaker brethren, who had been trampled upon and wiped out of existence in the general scramble for money. Such people were apt to reason like Thornton, who held that masters and men both had to run the risk of going under, and had no right to complain, if they did. Further it may be observed that the success these self-made men had achieved in life, tended itself again to bring out their bad qualities with all the greater force, while it suffocated the better hnpulses that lay latent in their characters. As in the case of Mr. Hillary, the great merchant in Warren's Diary of a Late Physician, the instinctive propensities of a low and coarse mind often made such men as tyrannical and insolent in success, as in their struggles they had been mean and abject. Finally we must keep in view the fact that as economists the business community took it as a law of nature that social misery was inevitable, being only due to the carelessness, improvidence, and a great many other vices of the lower classes. As Greg cynically puts it: "they have made for themselves the hard bed they lie on." 2 This was the generally received opinion of the orthodox economists, who had not progressed far enough in their social science to see that it was exactly their poverty and misery that prevented the poor from making another bed, and that it would be possible and necessary to raise their moral Standard by improving their material conditions of life. The only panacea of the economists was to teach the labouring classes the economie laws as they had been formulated by Ricardo and Malthus, thereby showing them that resignation was the best cure for all evils. Hence the unceasing efforts of people 1) Advice to Young Men, by William Cobbett. Introduction bv Henrv Morley, p. 5. ' 2) R. W. Greg, op. cit, p. 102. 35 like Jane Marcet, Miss Martineau, Fox, Nassau Senior, Whateley and others, to diffuse the knowledge of sound-i.e. orthodox-economie principles among the people, which efforts are satirized for instance in The Chimes, where Filer tells Richard and Meg that it is a crime for them to marry as long as the young man has no better prospects. Before concluding our chapter on the utilitarian man of business, we wish to make a final observation on the real character of these men. That the utilitarian economists sincerely believed the truth of their own teachings does not leave the slightest room for doubt. The tone of great sincerity, as well as the somewhat offensive assurance in putting forth their intellectual arguments, show that they really believed that the new science had all but reached the final degree of development. Nor were the Benthamites and individualists in their private lives the heartless monsters and cold rationalists their opponents have been used to call them, even down to the present time.1 Ricardo is described as an indulgent father and husband, an affectionate and zealous friend, who was never slow to come forward to the reliëf of the poor and the distressed, supporting at his own expense an almshouse and two schools for the poor.2 Bentham himself was at one time a partner in the firm running the New Lanark Mills on somewhat philanthropic principles. Even Engels, a vehement socialist writer of that time, is forced to admit that the English bourgeois of the mercantile and industrial class have all sorts of private virtues, appearing as decent and respectable as all other bourgeois, while "even in business they are better to deal with than the Germans." 3 In his Autobiography John Mill makes an observation about the discrepancy between his father's Malthusian principles of marriage, and the fact that in his own life he married rather improvidently and had a large family. John Mill himself is likewise in several respects open to the same charge of inconsistency. One instance of it is afforded by the remark Brandes made about him in 1870, after his wife's death, of whom he was 1) G. K. Chesterton even doubts whether Bentham had a soul! The Victorian Age in Literature, p. 36. London, 1920. 2) Introduction to Works, pp. XXIX, XXXI. London, 1852. 3) F. Engels, op. cit., p. 276. 36 constantly talking then. The Dane observed that Mill could not "be reproached with considering marriage a mere contract, as somethnes has been done owing to the extremely rational standpoint that he took up on the question of women." 1 This doublé aspect of the character of the members of the business community is also reflected in various novels of the Early Victorian times, especially in the social novels of Mrs. Gaskell and Charlotte Brontë, who both make an effective use of it for their treatment of psychological character development. Both Thornton in North and South, and Robert Moore in Shirley are hard and haughty in their factories, showing a pugnacious and bulldog spirit in their fights against the "hands," but in private life they show a quite different side of their character. What one of the mill-operatives said of Thornton, as regards his being "two chaps in one," is almost literally repeated of Robert Moore by that person himself, when he says: "I find in myself, Lina, two natures, one for the world and business, and one for home and leisure. Gérard Moore is a hard dog, brought up to mill and marketj'the person you call your cousin Robert, is sometimes a dreamer, who is elsewhere than in Cloth-Hall and Counting-house." In both manufacturers a gradual change is wrought, partly by the force of circumstances, but chiefly by love. The hard and selfish spirit of the utilitarian economist and man of business is forced into the background, while the more humane and humanitarian side of their character is strengthened. This shows itself in both novels in a greater interest taken in the welfare of the workmen, and in a more or less philanthropic management of their mills.2 1) Cited by Oliver Elton, A Survey of English Literature. 1830—1850. Vol. I, London, 1920. 2) The novels of the two friends present a strikingly large number of points of resemblance, too many perhaps to be put down entirely to mere coincidence. 37 CHAPTER II. Attacks on Utilitarianism and Political Economy» One of the earliest attacks made in literature upon the dominant body of thought represented by the combined teachings of Benthamites and economists, is found in Disraeli's story of Popanilla, which appeared in 1828, and whose chief aim is to hold up to scorn the utilitarian commercialism of the time. In the opening chapters there is a beautiful description of the happy life of the natives of the Isle of Fantaisie, somewhere in the Indian Ocean. "They are an innocent and happy, though a voluptuous and ignorant race. They have no manufactures, no commerce, no agrkulture, and no printing-presses; but for their slight clothing they wear the bright skins of serpents; for corn nature gives them the bread-fruit, and for intellectual amusement, they have a pregnant fancy and a ready wit ..." They are shown us as leading a sort of Arcadian life, without cares or troubles, dancing in the twilight or in the moonshine under the beautiful trees of their virgin forests, and sleeping in the daytime. But this happy and idle life is disturbed one day by the fact that one of them, Popanilla, who was "the delight of society and the especial favourite of the women," finds a chest full of books on the shore of the island. The study of these books opens the eyes of the native to the fact that his companions, hitherto regarded as "the most eligible portion of the visible creation," were nothing more than a "horde of useless savages." This conviction brought in its train a determination to enlighten his fellow-islanders on their deplorable condition, and to civilize them.1 "But he was determined," the author says, "not to be too 1) This is a satire of the efforts made by economists to enlighten the mass of the people on the causes of their miserable condition. Cf. pp. 35, 36. 38 rapid, as ancient prejudices cannot be eradicated in a moment, and new modes of conduct instantaneously substituted and established. Popanilla, like a wise man, determined to conciliate. His views were to be as liberal as his principles were enlightened. Men should be forced to do nothing. Bigotry, and intolerance, and persecution were the objects of his decided disapprobation." Here Disraeli lays his finger on one of the weakest spots in English Liberalism of the Early Victorian period. Its latitudinarianism must have been particularly hateful to a young man with a powerful imagination and an Oriental temperament like Disraeli. It was this same aversion to compromise and conciliation that caused him to attack the "Peelite" reconstruction of the Tory party in his subsequent novel Sybil. The only principle put into practice by those Conservatives, he says, was to give way constantly to their political opponents. In order to convert his ignorant companions to his utilitarian and commercial view of society, Popanilla makes them long speeches "in sentences which would not have disgraced the mellifluous pen of Bentham." The islanders, who seemed to think that their only object of life was to enjoy themselves, "to dance and sing, to crown themselves with chaplets, and to drink wine," were now told that there was no utility in pleasure, so that it could profit no one. "If, therefore, it was improfitable, it was injurious; because that which does not produce a profit, is equivalent to a loss; therefore pleasure is a losing business; consequently pleasure is not pleasant." This sally at Bentham's teachings was no doubt suggested by the fact that according to this philosopher the basis of social organisation was the greatest happiness—identified by the Benthamites with pleasure1—of the greatest number. Popanilla further showed his fellow-islanders that "man was not bom for himself, but for society; that the interests of the body alone are to be considered, and not those of the individual; and that a nation might be extremely happy, extremely powerful, and extremely rich, although every individual member of it might at the same time be miserable, dependent and in debt." 1) Graham Wallas, op. cit., p. 106. 39 In this passage Disraeli shows us the great fault attaching to political economy in its early stage. Instead of aiming at the promotion of the well-being of the citizens of the State, it only considered the welfare of the State itself in its theories. National wealth and power were the chief object of the author of The Wealth of Nations and his disciples, the orthodox economists. As a modern writer observes,1 the very name of political economy "suggests that the subject of study is not so much the welfare of human beings, as the advantage of States—although," he adds, "happily the study itself is more humane than its title." It is curieus to observe in this connection that there were even persons who spoke of the science as political arithmetic, showing that figures expressive of "wealth" were in their eyes the essence of economie studies. As regards the above view that the science itself is more humane than its title would lead us to expect, this may hold good for modern political economy, but it certainly could not be said of the doctrines of orthodox political economy. A very. striking and painful instance of the heartless indifference of economists of the Early Victorian period towards the welfare of the people when the interests of the business community and of the trade of England were concerned is afforded by what McCulloch, one of the most influential members of the orthodox school, wrote in his Dictionary of Commerce with reference to the import duties on spirits before the year 1786. "Our policy," he wrote, "if we may apply that term to so revolting a display of short-sightèd rapacity, had no other effect than to lessen the public revenue and the enjoyment of the people." But when Pitt had reduced the duty on "geneva" by 50 per cent.," the economist enthusiastically assures his readers, "the effect of his wise and politic measure was such" that in the next decennial period the imports for home consumption rose from 80,000 gallons to nearly'450,000 gallons. When we remember that these 450,000 gallons of gin had to be consumed by nine millions of people, we may well doubt, not only the wisdom and policy of Pitfs measure, but also whether in their individualism the orthodox economists saw deep enough 1) Conrad Gill, National Power and Prosperity, p. 89. London, 1916. 40 into their science to distinguish between the interests of the "State" and those of the individual units forming "society." The first English author that plainly set forth the mistake of the Utilitarians that the wealth of the State—an "enchanted wealth" and "the gold of Midas" he called it1—was the great object to be attained, was Carlyle. He showed his contemporaries that the prosperity of the People was quite a different thing, and this message is, as Chesterton calls it, his real glory.2 Another novelist who, like Disraeli, wrote about Bentham's utilitarian creed in those early days is Edward Bulwer. In his novel The Disowned, which appeared in the same year as Popanilla (1828), he describes the character of one Mr. Vavasour Mordaunt as follows: he was a "shrewd, sensible, ambitious man of the world, persevering, steady, erafty, etc.," to which the author adds that he was "what might be termed a mistaken utilitarian: he had lived utterly and invariably for self; but instead of uniting selfinterest with the interests of others, he considered them as perfectly incompatible ends." By this observation the author, who, as our readers remember, passed through a short period in his career when he was—or pretended to be—a disciple of the teachings of Bentham,8 clearly shows us that he was fully alive to the dangers Benthamism contained, if his famous self-interest principle coinciding with the general interests was used by a rascal as a cover for his malpractices. That those dangers were for from imaginary is easily proved by the doctrines of economists like Nassau Senior, who taught that "the pursuit of wealth ... is, to the mass of mankind, the great source of moral improvement",* and his successor at Oxford, Whately, who wrote in a similar strain,5 which statements are again mere repetitions of what the great master of the economists had written more than half a century before in his Wealth of Nations* There were a great many contemporaries of Bentham who, like Wedderburn, openly expressed O Past and Present, pp. 5, 6. London, 1919. 2) G. K. Chesterton, op. cit, p. 55. 3) L. Cazamian, op. cit., p. 90. 4) Cited by Cazamian, op. cit., p. 198 5) Cf. p. 14. 6) On page 12 we have quoted a very instructive passage. 41 Peacock's Crotchet Castte, which appeared in 1830. The author continually attacks and ridicules the Scottjsh school in the person of Mac Quedy, the economist, who "will talk to you about the exchangeable value by the hour" and "turns all the affairs of the world into buying and selling." Mac Quedy himself tells the other guests at the Castle that "in logic and moral philosophy (they)— i. e., in "sweet Edinbroo"—are at home," while "to all this (they) have added political economy, the science of sciences." (pp. 204, 195) The author who made the fiercest and most persistent attacks upon the creed of Bentham and his allies, the orthodox economists, philosophical radicals, and mill-owners of the Manchester school, was Charles Dickens. He must have deeply feit the nefarious influence utilitarian intellectualism exercised in his country, as practised by heartless economists, and by business people whose sole aim was to get rich by the aid of their "free competition" principle. It is not so much in business people like Scrooge, Ralph Nickleby, or Arthur Gride, that we must look for traces of Bentham's influence; they are represented to us rather as victims of avarice, and of the Mammonism of the period, whose altar, to use Disraeli's words, had blazed with triple worship since the passing of the Reform Act. Nor are we to look for a Benthamite economist in the person of Paul Dombey, whose besetting sin is heartless pride, but in whose character we do not read Dickens's intention of castigating the mercantile spirit of his age. It is rather in persons like Filer in The Chimes, and Bounderby and Gradgrind in Hard Times that the novelist attacks the all-pervading influence of the Utilitarians. Dickens wrote three stories in which these attacks occur with gradually increasing vigour. The first is found in the First Meeting of the Mudfog Association, a short satire appearing in Bentley's Miscellany (1837—39). Amongst a great many other "absurdities" observed by the author in the daily life around him, it is political economy that he makes fun of. He seems almost to identify the science with statistics.1 1) The early volumes of Punch also contain numerous passages in which statistics and statistical figures are ridiculed, e.g., vol. 1, p. 110; vol. II, p. 112. 43 Statistics was a comparatively new study at the time, which may be said to have been created by economists as a basis for their social investigations. One of the pioneers in these studies was a Scotch landed proprietor, Sir John Sinclair (f 1835), who is even said to have introduced the word "statistics" into English, to denote the researches economists were then beginning to make, in order to give a solid basis of reality to their teachings, which hitherto had been merely abstract speculations. Sinclair even adopted the modern method of circulating a number of queries to all the clergymen of his country, in order to obtain information about population, production, and other economie data. Another of those early statisticians, Sir Frederick Norton Eden, employed an agent who travelled about the country with a similar set of queries. It is evident that the collections of facts which thus became available to the students of political economy, must have been a valuable asset to them as a reliable basis for social theories. To Dickens, however, these "facts and figures," as he contemptuously denotes them over and over again, were merely signs of the deadening mathematical spirit animating Utilitarians and Economists in their study of social problems. In his eyes they were the men who, like Mr. Filer, had reduced such problems "to a mathematical certainty long ago," by means of their inquiries and statistics. Moreover utilitarian politicians made use of the materials thus collected in two manners that were both equally odious to a thoroughly humanitarian novelist like Dickens. In the first place they used statistical figures as a proof of the necessity of legislative measures like the much abused New Poor Law of 1834. The heartlessness of this piece of utilitarian legislation, inevitable and useful as it may have been, was demonstrated by Dickens in his workhouse story in Oliver Twist. That the facts as stated by him were no exaggeration is proved by the many instances of cruelty and harsh treatment of the paupers that may be found in books like Engels'. Of course it is quite another question whether the pauperism of those days, which had assumed appaUing proportions, could have been effectually checked in a humaner manner. Dickens's political friends, the Radicals, who got the measure through 44 Parliament, evidently thought not, and the results of this much abused piece of legislation have fully justified its introduction. In other cases again Dickens saw utilitarian economists use their statistical figures to prevent the introduction of legislation, if it interfered with their principle of "laissez-faire" and "free competition." This was especially the case when the humanitarians under the leadership of Shaftesbury, Sadler, Oastler, and others attempted to mitigate the evils of the factory system by legislative measures for the protection of its victims. The standpoint of political economists in these questions was absolutely the same as that of the parties interested in the maintenance of unbridled freedom in every direction, namely the mill-owners. The evils attendant upon this system, as we have described them briefly in a previous chapter, did not of course escape the notice of the economist, but he either laid the blame of all the misery at the door of the poor sufferers themselves, like Greg;1 or he simply declared that State interference was impotent for good; that the masses could not be raised out of their misery, but had to raise themselves; or again he said, as we read in Alton Locke, "that, however glad he would be to help (them), it was impossible—he could not alter the laws of nature—that wages were regulated by the amount of competition among the men themselves," which is the same kind of reasoning as that of John Thornton in North and South, who also showed "on sound economie principles" that in periods of depression "a certain number of masters as well as of men must go down into ruin," against which the heroine's heart rose up in revolt, "as if commerce were everything, and humanity nothing." How the figures collected by statisticians were used as a powerful weapon by the Manchester school to resist humanitarian measures is strikingly illustrated by the speech one of them made in Parliament in the course of a debate on the protection of workmen in the mills. This member, John Bright, said, "It was proposed the other day to spend millions in boxing off our machinery. We have in our mills about a thousand workpeople. In fifteen years we have had five accidents. We have three carters. In the same space of time two of them have been killed ...2 1) Cf. p. 35. 2) Cited by Dicey, op. cit, p. 236. 45 In the proceedings of the above-mentioned Mudfog Association we read among others of one the members, Mr. X. Leadbrain, reading "a very ingenious communication, from which it appeared that the total number of legs belonging to the manufacturing population of one great town in Yorkshire was, in round numbers, forty thousand, while the total number of chair and stool legs in their houses was only thirty thousand, which, upon the very favourable average of three legs to a seat, yielded only ten thousand seats in all. From this calculation it would appear—not taking wooden or cork legs into account, but allowing two legs to every person—that ten thousand individuals (one half of the whole population) were either destitute of any rest for their legs at all, or passed the whole of their leisure time in sitting upon boxes." 1 In his second great Christmas story Dickens repeats his attack on what might be called the "social mathematicians" by drawing the picture of Mr. Filer, who denounces poor Toby Veck for eating tripe on the great man's doorstep.2 "But who eats tripe?" said Mr. Filer, looking round. "Tripe is without an exception the least economical, and the most wasteful article of consumption that the markets of this country can by possibility produce. The loss upon a pound of tripe has been found to be, in the boiling, seven eighths of a fifth more than the loss upon a pound of any other animal substance whatever. Tripe is more expensive, properly understood, than the ho thou se pine-apple.8 Taking into account the number of animals slaughtered yearly within the bills of mortality alone; and forming a low estimate of the quantity of tripe which the carcasses of those animals, reasonably well butchered, would yield; I find that the waste on that amount of 1) Stories and Sketches, p. 408. London and Olasgow. 2) Christmas Books, p. 81. London. 3) Op. cit., vol. II, book IV, p. 35. This "hothouse pine-apple" is a satire of one of the favourite illustrations used by orthodox economists to prove that unimpeded freedom of production and trade in general are the essential conditions for a sound economie development of a country, and that a large quantity of labour is wasted in consequence of different countries striving to produce commodities for which they are utterly unsuitable. Adam Smith had first illustrated the argument by vine grapes that could, if required, be grown in Scotland. 46 tripe, if boiled, would victual a garrison of five hundred men for five months of thirty-one days each, and a February over." At which lengthy economie al and statistical disquisition poor old Trotty stood aghast. "He seemed to have starved a garrison of five hundred men with his own hand." 47 he is "banker, merchant, manufacturer, and what not," but the author does not show us the great man in any of his multifarious pursuits. For a story purporting to strike a blow on behalf of the manufacturing labourer this is a great defect. The reader would have wished to witness a struggle between the two hostile powers in industry that have faced each other ever since in endles conflicts, with a clear exposition of all the principles and passions moving them. Nothing of all this is to be found in Hard Times. The wage question is not even mentioned in it, unless we take Mr. Bounderby*» parrotlike cry that "they all want to be fed on turtle soup and venison and eat with a gold spoon" as a treatment of it. What Dickens says of the mill-owners of Coketown as a class is also little more than the general observations that were current at that time among philanthropists, and which were commonly drawn from the parliamentary speeches made by representatives of the Manchester school. The "millers" complained of their being ruined, if they had to send factory children to school, admit inspectors to their mills, protect their hands from being injured by the machines, prevent the smoke from their chimneys from becoming a nuisance,1 etc All these remarks may be found in Hansard and are repeated in much the same strain in books like Dr. Ure's Philosophy of Manufactures. Mr. Gradgrind, the embodiment of political economy as Dickens fancied it was, is less successful from a literary point of view. Of the inner workings of his mind we perceive very little. Perhaps the author omitted on purpose to endow him with any spiritual hfe, to show us, how dead his soul really was, but still we cannot help thinking that as a human picture he is not a great success. He is intended to represent the barren influence of rationahsm and Benthamism in private life, just as Parliament, "the national cinderheap " was the social outcome of this school of thought. Two of Gradgrind's children were called Adam Smith and Malthus and their eminently practical father had them trained to mathematical exactness. Everything in and about his household in as cold and mathe- 1) The smoke nuisance of the numerous factory chimneys s referred to, not only in Hard Times, but also in North ^SoMp. 55,Pa^ and Present, p. 254; Popanilla, p. 409 (Novels and Tales, vol. IV, London, 1881). 52 matical as the house and its very name of Stone Loöge itself. But Gradgrind is painted too much upon the easy method of mannerisms and peculiarities, tricks of speech or of carriage which Dickens adopted so often. Dickens's hatred of figures and averages—the wickedest and most enormous vice of the time, as he wrote to his friend Charles Knight1 —led him to a violent attack upon the schoolmaster Mr. M'Choakumchild, who, with "some one hundred and forty other schoolmasters, had lately been turned at the same time, in the same factory, on the same principles, like so many pianoforte legs." The author exclaims that if this man, who only inculcates facts in the juvenile minds, but murders every tracé of fancy there, "had only learned a little less", he "might have taught much more." This sally curiously contrasts with the general principles of enlightenment so strenuously advocated by the very men whose opinions must have been the most congenial to the author, such as the above-mentioned Knight, the editor of the Penny Magazine, a popular periodical for the spread of knowledge among the masses.2 It might also lead modern readers not conversant with the history of English elementary education, to believe that English schoolmasters were already suffering from an excess of learning a little more than ten years after State aid had first been granted for the upkeep of training colleges for teachers, and less than ten years after Government had begun to grant State aid for the payment of staffs possessing a certificate of competence. Though she does not, like Dickens, single out some special department of political economy for her attacks, Mrs. Gaskell's opinion of the social science is hardly more favourable. We can gather this from a conversation between an old spinner, Job Legh, and a mill-owner, Mr. Carson, in Mary Barton.3 In the course of their interview the workman says to the master that he is not given to political economy. When the latter talks of facts having proved the desirability of self-reliance for the workers, Job replies that "you can never work facts as you would fixed quantities, and say, given two facts, and the product is so and so. God has given men feelings and passions which cannot be worked into the problem, 1) Hard Times, Introduction, p. XII. 2) Imitated in this country by the Penning Magazijn. 3) Mary Barton, p. 454. 53 CHAPTER IV. Free Enterprise* Besides its statistical inquiries and arguments, contemptuously denoted by Dickens as "stutterings", there were also other aspects of the gospel of business^ people that attracted the notice of Early Victorian novelists, and were commented upon in their works. One of these, which undoubtedly deserves to be mentioned first, was the principle of free competition, both in its more restricted business acceptation of all efforts made to undersell and cut out others in the same trade, and as a term of political economy, to denote what is generally called "free enterprise", i.e., those social conditions which leave every citizen entirely free in the pursuits he has selected as the most suitable for himself. A third form of free competition, namely that in trading with foreign countries, usually denoted as free trade, also finds some weak echoes in Early Victorian fiction. Disraeli is again one of the earliest writers of the period that treat of competition. In Popanilla we find a humorous caricature of competition between shopkeepers in a description of what happened to the hero in a shop in Hubbabub, which is London. Popanilla entered this shop for the purpose of buying a purse, and was told that its price was four crowns, upon which the proprietor of the opposite establishment ran in to offer him one for three crowns. The original shopkeeper then reduced his price to two crowns. His rival next offering a purse gratis, he also offered) the customer one on the same terms, with a crown inside. When Popanilla put this purse into his pocket, his companion explained to him that this was not "Cheating" as he had innocently called it, but "Competition". In Past and Present Carlyle also makes frequent references to business competition, and his words have, as was to be expected, a deeper sense than the above witty sally of young Disraeli. The 55 which fact induced the local authorities to refrain from making use of the Settlement Act. In Afary Barton we are told that after the death of the mill operative Davenport the Board, instead of sending the widow back to her husband's parish, allowed her to stay in Manchester, and even paid the rent for her miserable area dwelling. From the same novel we have already cited an example illustrating the gradual shifting of the rural population to the new centres of industry, and proving that the "free labour market" had actually been created by the new economie circumstances. Disraeli speaks in Sybil of the agricultural labourers being "sent down by Pickford's van into the labour market to bring down (the) wages." 1 It was especially the great prosperity enjoyed for a time by the handloom weavers which induced numerous field labourers to take up that calling. But during the succeeding period of the war with France this swollen market led to great disasters, and the weavers suffered great hardship, which was soon aggravated by the introduction of the powerloom.2 In Sybit the hard lot of such an unfortunate workman is described in the person ofWarner the handloom weaver.8 In 1844 Engels spoke of "workmen on tramp", in search of employment in other towns, a phrase that is likewise used by Thornton in North and South; when he speaks of the necessity of shutting up shop, he says "that hands and masters (may) go alike on tramp." In Hard Times it is Stephen Blackpool, the mill hand, who leaves Coketown with his bundie under his arm, to seek work elsewhere. One of the greatest competitors in the free labour market appears to have been the Irish immigrant. Bad as the social conditions of England were in those days, there is no doubt that in Ireland the state of affairs was still infinitely worse. Going about in rags, eating nothing but potatoes, and sleeping in a pig-sty, the Irishman was eager to work for the starvation wages that an English workman, who was still somewhat civilized, as Engels observes, could not live upon. We get a glimpse of the Standard of life the Irishman maintained at home in Barry Lyndon, in passages like the following: "I found her (i.e., Molly, a girl the speaker had known before), a slatternly'wench in a mud hut, surrounded by a brood of 1) Sybil, p. 121. 2) W. Cunningham, op. cit., p. 633. 3) Sybit, pp. 140—153. 61 children almost as ragged as those of my friend the blacksmith," 1 and a complete picture of Ireland in those days is drawn in William Carlton's voluminousTra/ïs and Stories of the Irish Peasantry, in which Pat is depicted with his family, his pig and, like the Arabian and his horse, all sleeping in the same bed, the pig generally, for the sake of convenience, next the "stock", i.e., at the outside.2 It is no wonder that the close vicinity of the great Lancashire cotton district tempted many a poor Irish devil to cross St. George's Channel, and seek work in the mills there. Carlyle says in Chartism: "Crowds of Miserable Irish darken all our towns." They were not readily taken on, however, except in case of great shortage of labour, for instance when a strike was on at the mills. In such cases millowners availed themselves of Irish labour as knobsticks, and even sent over to Ireland sometimes to import large numbers of them. We read this in North and South, where Thornton, at the advice of his mother, orders forward a large gang of them, who are lodged in one of the wings of his mill, as they dare not leave the premises for fear of being molested. Of course such people were but very poor substitutes for the regular operatives. The work in the mill was new to them, and their aptitude to learn it was no doubt very small in view of their utter lack of civilization. We are therefore not surprised to hear that Thornton had not been able to execute his orders, "owing in some degree to the utter want of skill of the Irish hands" and that "much of their work was damaged and unfit to be sent forth." Engels, who devotes a whole chapter of his book to the problem of Irish immigration, accurately weighed the value of such "hands" when he said: "The newly hnmigrated Irishman, encamped in the first stable that offers, or turned out in the street after a week, because he spends everything upon drink and cannot pay rent, would be a poor mill-hand." We need not be surprised to find, in view of the above facts, that philanthropists and humanitarian reformers looked upon this Irish influx with anything but sympathetic feelings. They fully realized that as long as those people continued to work at starvation wages, not only no improvement for English workmen would be possible, but that, as Carlyle said, "the condition of the lower multitude of 1) Works, vol. XII, p. 213. London, 1878. 2) Vol. I, p. 410. London, 1843. 62 English labourers approximate(d) more and more to that of the Irish." This expiains the great dislike of Irishmen so frequently expressed by authors writing about the condition-of-England question. Carlyle depicts the "Sanspotatoes" in the following flattering terms: "The wild Milesian features, looking false ingenuity, restlessness, unreason, misery, and mockery, salute you on all the highways and byways," and he covers a whole page of Chartism in the same strain.1 Charles Kingsley is equally prejudiced against the poor Irishman. In Alton Locke he heaps contemptuous ridicule on the person of Kelly, depicts a despicable demagogue and low-grade journalist in the character of O'Flynn, and a traitor of his fellowworkmen, who later on turns sweater, in Jemmy Downes. Christian Socialists, the men who, as we shall presently see, had devised practical methods for combating the evils of free labour competition, had of course a special inducement to be thus prepossessed against the wretched immigrants that aggravated the very evils they wished to suppress. When novelists make reference to the economie notion of a free labour market, it is always, as was to be expected, in a somewhat sarcastic strain. Carlyle was the first to draw a caricature of this politico-economic innovation, with its wages depending upon supply and demand, just as prices in all other markets.2 "My starving men," says the rich mill-owner: "Did I nothire them fairly in the market? Did I not pay them, to the last sixpence, the sum covenanted for?" This refers to the utter absence of any human tie between masters and men under the new system. In another passage he speaks of the "lawlèss anarchy of supply and demand," where "market wages alone" are paid, while the so-called freedom of the labourer to seek the best market for his work is ridiculed, by comparing him to a horse: "The master of horses, when the summer labour is done, has to feed his horses through the winter. If he said to his horses: Quadrupeds, I have no longer work for you, but work exists abundantly over the world: are you ignorant (or must I read you Political Economy Lectures) that the steam engine always in the long run creates additional work? Railways are forming in one quarter of this earth, canals in another, much cartage is wanted; 1) Collected Works, vol IX, p. 18. London, 1858. 2) Past and Present, pp. 141, 187, 254. 63 and to alrow them to reap the full benefit of their work. The divine spirit of association was thus to take the place of the unchristian system of selfish competition devised by a heartless and rational school of economists. But these associations could only prosper, when carried on as commercial enterprises, for they had to compete in their business with individualistic firms, so that at bottom these associated workmen acted on the same principles of. selfishness and profit-making as their rivals. When this was pointed out clearly by the bookbinder Sully, there were idealistic leaders like Maurice, who at first in their misplaced idealism protested against this view of the movement, while economie writers like Greg were not slow in pointing out that the hateful competition the Christian Socialists sought to kill, was only introduced into society by them in another form. They found no difficulty in proving the fact by merely citing, as Greg did, the very words used by Kingsley ir, his above-mentioned pamphlet Cheap Clothes and Nasty. "We will hoard our profits," Kingsley had written there, "and not spend them till we have squeezed out all the sweaters one by one. Then we will open our common shop, and sell at as low a price as the cheapest of the show shops ... Let us then encourage the journeymen to compete with Nebuchadnezzar & Co. at their own game In this, as in many other questions, it appears that an idealistic reformer often has but very hazy notions of the full bearing of his own remedies. Early Victorian literature affords numerous other instances, where humanitarian novelists fall into the same error of combating competition by identically the same economie weapon. Kingsley himself does so in another passage in Alton Locke, where he describes what he calls "Lord Ellerton's perfections." This nobleman is a landed proprietor with a deep sense of the high duties of a landlord, which he shows by his measures of improvement: one of these is to expel the old bankrupt race of farmers from his estate, and to advertise widely for men of capital and science, at the same time lowering his rents. The author does not seem to be aware that this/ is tantamount to competing with other landlords, by drawing the best farmers from their estates. Similarly Lord Ellerton gave his cottages to "the most intelligent artisans whom he could draft from the manufacturing town hard by." 65 In Past and Present Carlyle tells us of "a practical manufacturing Quaker," whom he calls Friend Prudence. "Prudence keeps a thousand workmen; has atriven in all ways to attach them to hhn; h«8 given conversational soirées; play-grounds; bands of music for the young ones; went even the length of buying them a drum; all which has turned out an excellent investment." Next Carlyle describes another master with a thousand men, who has done nothing for them: they "are perpetually getting into mutiny» into broils and Disraeli likewise describes a miU-owner who does everything in his power to promote the moral and material welfare of his men and their families. This Mr. Trafford also succeeds in this way in getting together a model staff at bis works, But both Carlyle and Disraeli seem to have: entirely overlooked the fact again that such humane mill management brings into play the very competition in the free labour market which they and their friends denounce as the greatest evil of orthodox economy. Instead of furnishing arguments for the necessity of a humane treatroent of mill hands by their employers, their examples go to prove the usefulness of a free market where every master can take his choice. The higher moral tone and the greater efficiency of Prudence's and Trafford's staffs can neithef be put down entirely to the humane treatment they receive at the hands oi their masters, as Carlyle aad Disraeli wish to show by their illustrations. There is a second factor ia bringing about this superiority of such staffs. By their philanthropic management masters like Friend Prudence and Trafford attract into their service only the steadiest class of workisg people, while the more inoorrigible ones, those who are not amenable to moral influences, soon leave such uncongenial and in their eyes duit and saintrlike enviroos. This fact is strikingly though probably unwittingly illustrated by Disraeli himself. He tells us of one of the factory ghls, Caroline by name, who has left Mr. Trafford's mui. She fully admits that it is a great thing for a young person to be employed there already, "but then it was so dull and then Iamno scholar, and never could take to learning. And those Traffords had so many schools." In another coaversation the same girl complains that "at the Traffords' the greatest fun (they) ever had was a singing-class." 66 Free trade, the third form of free competition, is almost entirely left undiscussed by Early Victorian literature, which may seem strange, as it was one of the principal tenets of orthodox economists. In Past and Present Carlyle shows himself an advocate of an unrestricted trade with foreign markets, chiefly in connection with the Corn Laws that were still in force in 1843, but were already doomed to disappear in consequence of the unwearying propaganda of men like Cobden and Bright with their Anti-Corn Law League. As one of Carlyle's biographers points out, Carlyle is somewhat inconsistent in this matter: though advocating free trade, and agreeing with the British policy of coercion with regard to China, for the purpose of compelling the Celesta! Empire to open its ports to English traders, yet he condemns the same free' dealings between dass and class at home.1 As far as we remember, -there is only one other author of the Early Victorian period that refers to the Corn Laws, namely Disraeli, who in Popanilla attacks the aristocracy for the high prices they exact from the people for their corn.» In his later political novels, when he had staked out the direction of his future career, he carefully abstained from making any reference to this question. In Popanilla he advocates the principle of non-interference, not only with regard to the import of corn, but for all foreign trade as weü as in the colonial policy of his country. 1) J. Nicholl, Thomas Carlyle, p. 210. London, 1918. 2) See also note 3, p. 57. 67 CHAPTER V. The New Rich. Like all great social upheavals, the French wars and the Industrial Revolution in England were attended with the phenomenon so wellknown to students of present-day economy that the large masses of the people became desperately poor, while the accumulated wealth came into the hands of a small class of new rich. These new capitalists, having generally risen from the lower ranks of society still bore the stamp of their origin and mostly lacked the necessary culture to occupy their new rank in life in a proper mannen The first Early Victorian author that used this theme in his work is Disraeli. "Butlers were at a premium, coachmakers never slept," he tells us in describing the immense trade boom in the Island of Vraiblusia, which is England, the country of the True Blues. Coaches were in his time considered to be an unmistakable sign of the owners belonging to the upper ten thousand, and were almost held to be the exclusive privilege of the nobility. There are frequent references to this fact both in the literature and the history of the period. When a man had made a fortune, he—or more often than not his wife— set up a carriage, as a proof that he had arrived, as the French say, and intended "to sink the shop for the rest of (his) days," as Mr. Hillary put it.1 Thus we see Tittlebat Titmouse, as soon as he has come into a large fortune, hurry to a fashionable tailor's first, and then to a ditto coachmaker's. Mrs. Turnbull, the rich whaler captain s spouse in Jacob Faithful, likewise sports a fine coach in her London suburb. There is no doubt, however, that it still required some pluck in a rich "tradesman" to drive in his own carriage, and the equipages 1) Samuel Warren, The Diary of a Late Physician, vol. II, p. 277. London, 1844. 68 in Hyde Park still belonged to "the fashionable world," middle class people not appearing there.1 This is evident from an account given in Disraeli's papers of an incident that took place in Parliament shortly after the Reform of 1832. Sir Francis Burdett one day tokf the assembled members that on the occasion of a Parliamentary election his means had been crippled to such an extent that Lady Burdett had only one norse to her carriage. "The effect of this remark," Disraeli says "on one of the early reformed Parliaments, full of retired tradesmen, many of whom had assumed wealth, but had never plucked up courage to keep a carriage, may be conceived." 2 Many of those nouveaux fiches of course also tried to emblazon their wealth by a coronet. Disraeli sarcastically says in Popanilla, that "the demand for arms at the Herald's College was so great that even the mystical genius of Garter was exhausted." There is an Observation in Emilia Wyndham to the same effect: the author of this novel speaks of "the rich harvest of knights of all descriptions and for all reasons—the happy result of our victories both in arms and commerce." In Sybil Disraeli also refers to the large "infusion from the middle class" into the patrician party by Sir William "Petty", who made peers of "second-rate squires and fat-graziers", while he also "caught them in the alleys of 'Lombard Street and clutched them from the counting-houses of Cornhill." 8 A very lucrative business appears to have sprung up in this line, for in Sybil we read of the large fortune the heraldist Mr. Hatton, "a discoverer, inventor, framer, arranger of pedigrees", has succeeded in amassing by assisting his numerous clients in their suits to the Herald's Office. Other wealthy business people again, like the above-named Mr. Hillary, are trying to satisfy their ambitions by seeking for their daughter a son-in-law "that will clap a coronet on her head," but caring very little all the while whether by so doing they are promoting the child's happiness. In the same way Mrs. Dudley's vain imagination is dazzled by the notion of intermingling her blood with 1) H. D. Traill and J. S. Mann, Social England, vol. VI. 2) W. F. Monypenny, The Life of Benjamin Disraeli, Earl of Beaconsfield, vol. II, pp. 368, 369. London, 1912. 3) Sybit, p. 28. 69 "Nkmility".1 Thackeray's recipe for such people is: "Doublé your name, and stick an "e" to the end of it, and you are a gentleman at once." s The counterpart of the rich tradesman desirous of being ennobled is also met with in literature, though not so frequently. We mention Viscount Scamp, whose marriage with Mr. Hillary's daughter "would place his f inancial marters upon an entirely new basis," while further there is the Scotch earl in Marryafs novel The Pirate, "who went to London with a bevy of nine (girls) in a Leith smack, to barter blood for wealth." In connection with Miss Osborne's marriage in Vanity Fair Thackeray speaks of a "host of fashionables who have all married into Lombard Street, and done a great deal to ennoble Cornhill."3 We need not be surprised at the comparative scarcity of noblemen of this sort in literature, however. In the first place the English nobility of the period were wealthy landed proprietors, with inalienable rights in their propertjes, who as a rule need seek no alliances with tradesmen's families for the purpose of gilding their arms, while further the gulf between them and the trading and manufacturing classes was still so great at that time that Marryat tells us of a younger son of a patrician family going into a banking house, who, in consequence of this step was "as decidedly cut by his relations as a young lady, had she committed a faux pas." * Lady Marney in Sybil speaks of "some monster of the middle class, some tinker or candlestick-maker," who will stand for their borough, "with his long purse, preaching reform, and practising corruption," while her son considers manufactories to be "enterprises for the canaille." The width of the gulf between "tradespeople" and aristocrats is also clearly shown in a passage in Lady Shelley's Diary, where she tells us that her father, who lived at Preston, had become "disgusted with the erection of factories" near that place, which was the residence of the nobility and the county families. "One day," she says, "my father left his oW house, never to return. He had gone as usual in the morning to select his fish for dinner. On his arrrval 1) The Diary of a Late Physician. 2) Cox's Diary; Works, vol. III. London, 1899. 3) Vanity Fair, p. 537. 4) The Pirate, Ch. I 70 at the fishmonger's, he found himself forestalled in the purchase of the finest turbot by a Mr. Horrocks, a cotton spinner."1 This happened at a time when advertisers in The TUnes addressed themselves to "the nobility, gentry, and the publicl" When reading all the satirical observations made by novelists upon the aspirations of the rising business classes to become members of the old aristocratie caste, one cannot help thinking that there is a good deal in their pfetures that is due, not to actual facts observed in daily life, but to literary traditions handed down from preceding stages in the development of the novel. The poor young noble seeking to fill his empty coffers by a marriage with a wealthy middle class girl is too common a type in the literature of every country to be considered a special feature of the Early Victorian period. Many are the satires levelled in fiction at thë supposed or real lack of good manners of the new middle classes. Disraeli devotes a whole page to their description in Popanilla* The c har act er is tic of the many millionaires produced by the economie conditions Of the Island of Vraiblusia was the snub nose. When the new people had imitated the old aristocracy in the display of wealth and luxuiy, they found out to their dismay that they did not know how behave in society. "Accustomed to the counting-house, the factory, or the exchange, they looked queer in saloons, and said "Sir!" when they addressed you; and seemed stiff and hard and hot." 2 "But," the young author continues, "help was soon forthcoming to these would*be aristocrats." Treatises and dissertations appeared for the distribution of fashionable knowledge, just as in recent years we have seen advertisements appear in the papers, in which similar knowledge was offered to be taught to War Pröfiteers. It may wel! be said indeed that there Is nothing new under the sunl The Vraiblusian Government also took the matter of educating the new millionaires in hand. It issued an edict for the invention of a new literature, in consequenoe of which "Burlington, A Tale of 1) The Diary of Frances Lady Shelley, p. 3. London, 1912. That "tradesmen" had always experienced much difficulty in obtaining due recognition of their merits from other classes, appears from the fact that Defoe thought it necessary to devote no fewer than nine pages to prove "the Dignity, Antiquity, and other Honours due to Trade" to the "self-vain Gentry that would decry Trade as a universal Mechanism." A Plan of the English Commerce etc, by Daniël Defoe, pp. 5—13. London, 1728. 2) Novels and Tales, vol. IV, p. 428. 71 Fashionable Life, in three volumes post octavo" was set forth. One cannot help thinking that we have to do here with a satire of the Silver Fork School, which represented a class of fiction that was extremely popular at that time, though literary critics! do not agree as to the cause of that popularity. Some say that the large sale of the works of Theodore Hook and his followers was due to the fact that middle-class readers eagerly bought them, in order to complete their detective education; others again are inclined to believe that they owed their popularity to the satire they contained upon the unpopular and envied new rich. Possibly the sales of these novels may have been stimulated by both causes. A more violent, though far less witty attack upon the manners of the trading and manufacturing classes is to the found in Samuel Warren's Ten Thousand a Year. It is given in a description of the newly reformed Parliament of 1832, and is no doubt sorely biassed by political prejudices, the author repeatedly showing himself a thorough True Blue in his book} JHe says of the new House that it almost turned John Bull's stomach out, when he saw it, for "as far as outward appearance and behaviour went, there seemed scarcely fifty gentlemen among them." 'it was," the author adds, "as though the scum had risen to the surf ace of the caldron." That the new House was indeed quite different from the old ones is no doubt true. The time was past, when members went up to Westminster provkled with quotations collected from their Latin grammar,1 and when reporting of their speeches was considered a breach of privilege by them.2 The fashionable young gentleman representing a rotten borough had been replaced by some earnest business-man representing a large manufacturing town in the North. No wonder that the new debaters showed more passion, and even violence, if need be, than the old' orators. When portraying merchants and manufacturers in private life, novelists also frequently show them as awkward men, feeling ill at ease in drawing-rooms and at social functions. Tittlebat Titmouse can hardly be given as a specimen of such portraits, as he was only a "counter-jumper," not a business-man. Warren has drawn us a 1) Wellington is said to have done this. Walpole, History of England, vol. IV, p. 11, note. 2) lbid., p. 6. 72 fine specimen, however, in the person of Mr. Dudley,1 a self-made merchant and a worthy man, "a rich and racy specimen of one of those glories of our nation,—a true English merchant." The author shows here an appreciation of the merits of the mercantile class that is but too rare in the literature of his time, and even Warren's appreciation is limited to some eulogistic expressions but rarely showing itself in the manner in which he delineates the mercantile character or describes the social functions performed by trade and industry. In the character of Mr. Dudley the author has made us feel the restricted circle of interest and the limitations of the businessman's mind: "he could never be said to breathe freely—and really to live —'but in the City." This is of course chiefly to be accounted for by the lack of an all-round education of this merchant. Indeed, the author himself says that Mr. Dudley "was seldom or never to be seen amid the throng and crush of company that crowded his house evening after evening. The first arrival of his wife's guests was his usual sign for seizing his hat and stick, dropping quietly from home whereupon he used to repair to a simple place in the City, where he spent his evening in simple company. It was not only from not feeling at home in such circles that this merchant evaded them, but also for another reason: he is described to us as an economical, and even parsimonious man in his habits, so that we need not be surprised to see that the extravagant splendour of his wife's domestic arrangements are highly uncongenial to the simple-minded business-man. And even though not from any motive of parsimony, yet a wealthy tradesman may, like Captain Turnbull in Jacob Faithful, feel in his own drawing-room "like a buil in a China shop," simply because he wishes to live quietly and happily. The helpless attitude of the self-made man in fashionable circles has perhaps never been better portrayed than by Dickens in the person of Mr. Merdle, the great speculator in Little Dorrit, who "carries the shop on his back rather—like Jewish clothesmen with too much business," as his witty son-in-law, Mr. Sparkler, puts it. Mr. Merdle can accommodate himself so badly to the society his wife is dragging him about in that though the latter may announce "that 1) The Diary of a Late Physician, vol. II, p. 406. 73 lines, intending to make it pay.1 Squire Lavington would not, from ignorance and indolent habits, adopt such modern methods, but it is evident that small holders with properties often mortgaged up to the hilt, could not follow the Lord's example. It is curious to observe that men like Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, and other leaders of the laissez-faire school of economics, who unwearyingly advocated the principle of absolute freedom and the natural growth of society, strenuously opposed the extinction of the small man in agriculture, which was nevertheless one of the corollaries of growing capitalism. Their belief was that the small proprietor was the most industrious and the most succesful of all land-improvers.2 Attempts were also made to check the tendency to stamp out the Peasant Proprietary, and it is a curious sign of the spirit of the Early Victiorian period that one of the best-known of these attempts took the form of a joint stock enterprise: in 1844 Feargus O'Connor, the great Chartist leader, founded the National Land Company, whose shareholders were entitled to ballot for small holdings with a house, but which had to be wound up in consequence of the illegality of the lottery that was thus connected with it Of the great effects the above changes had on the conditions of life of the farm-labourers, which are described m Yeast, and likewise in Disraeli's Sybil, we need not speak here, as they fall outside the limits of this work. The Early Victorian novel gives almost as many instances of business people who became landed proprietors as the history of the time itself. We need only remind our readers of some of them. "Whatever capital he could spare from his business, he never sunk in speculation, but took a patriarchal pleasure in investing it in land,"—thus we read of John Halifax, and the author adds that he did so, "chiefly for the benefit of his mills and those concerned therein,"3 evidently seeing no other alternative for surplus capital to be safely employed. Halifax wishes to emulate the Cannings, Huskissons, and Peels, he tells his children, when he goes to live at Beechwood Hall, "to found a family" there, as his eldest son exclaims with sparkling eyes. 1) Yeast, pp. 85, 86. 2) See quotations given by Parker, op. cit., p. 169. 3) John Halifax, vol. II, p. 140. 81 In Dickens's novel Hard Times it is the manufacturer Bounderbv who becomes a landed proprietor by buying an estate at some distance from Coketown. In Yeast there is another instance of a "tradesman's family" changing into landed proprietors. Mr. Obadiah Newbroom had stood behind a loom when he began life, but he ended as a member of a large firm of cotton-lords, as the cotton manufacturers were often called in those days. What the father had begun with little means, his son continued with great ones, and finally the latter bought Minchampstead Park, and became Lord Minchampstead. Of course the Squires of the county at first swore at the "Parvenue", but we have no doubt they will soon have given that up. As we observed already in a previous chapter, the really wealthy class in the early decades of the nineteenth century were still the landed proprietors with their tens of thousands of acres of ground, and rent-rolls likewise running into tens of thousands sometimes. The novels of the period give various hints that bear out this fact. In The Disowned some one congratulates "my dear Linden" upon his accession to fortune: "five thousand a year, Scardale, and eighty thousand pounds in the funds." In Samuel Warren's Diary of a Late Physician we read of a rent-roll of twenty-five thousand pounds, and not less than two hundred thousand pounds in the funds. Tittlebat Titmouse, the hero of the same author's Ten Thousand a Year, inherits a large estate with a rent-roll of twenty-thousand per annum. Ainsworth's novel The Spendthrift opens with the words: "Heir to twenty thousand a year at twenty-one!" Finally there is a passage in the above-mentioned Diary, in which the author clearly states the fact that in point of wealth the noble landlords came first. It says that the sons of very few of the highest nobility had handsomer allowances, when studying at Oxford, than the rich merchant Mr. Dudley's son.1 1) Vol. I, p. 418. How greatly circumstances have altered in the nineteenh century appears from the following passage in W. H. Mullock's book Social Reform etc. (London, 1914): The landrent in this country, relatively to the national income, is a fraction which, instead of increasing constanüy, grows less and less. In the year 1801 the landrent of England and Wales amounted to 20 % of a total income of £ 180 miflions. To-day, out of a total income of more than £ 2000 millions, it barely amounts to so much as 4 % (p. 203). See also J. C. Stamp, British Incomes and Property, p. 49. London, 1916. 82 Over against the above details we can place some data, likewise furnished by literature, about the fortunes possessed by rich people of the trading classes. Captain Turnbull, a retired whaler captain and shipowner in Jacob Faithful, left at his death a fortune 'amounting in all to close upon eighty thousand pounds. Mr. Hillary, the rascal porfrayed in the Diary of a Late Physician, intends to give his daughter a plum on her marrying Viscount Scamp, and Warren calls the same person "a stupid millionaire." The Norton Bury Mercury, a newspaper mentioned in John Halifax, speaks of the "grasping plebeian millionaires," meaning the wool-spinners. We think, however, that the term "millionaire" must be taken here, as in so many other instances, cum grano salis. It is a fascinating word, and a very convenient manner to denote some rich person, but in many cases the truth will no doubt fall far short of the six noughts. The imagination of the superficial and especially the poor observer is often so affected by a few conspicuous cases of large fortunes that he is led to believe that they are the rule instead of the exception.1 Probably Mrs. Gaskell, who knew the cotton spinners and other mill owners of Manchester intimately, is nearer the mark, when in Mary Barton she speaks of the tens of thousands these had made by their trade. Ure, writing of English manufactures in 1835, refers to the "very great number of Bills of Exchange, rather small in their character, yet the aggregate well kept up," 2 while in the same chapter the author speaks of persons beginning with large capitals not succeeding so well in general, as those who begin with small ones cautiously administered. There are further a great many evidences in contemporary fiction and political and social literature that the greatest accumulations of capital were in those days in the hands, not of the manufacturing classes, but of the loanmongers, speculators, and other financiers of the period of the wars, and of the people who had returned from the colonies after making a fortune there. Accurate data as to mercantile incomes will not be easily obtainable, at least not before 1842, when an Income Tax was levied 1) A very interesting anecdote is told in this connection by Andrew Carnegie in his book The Empire of Business. 2) This statement he had found in the Report of the Committee of Manufactures, Commerce and Shipping of 1833. 83 for the first time in England.1 The national capital, estimated at £ 2700 millions in 1812, had risen to £ 4000 millions in 1845, and the population from 18 millions in 1811 to 27 millions in 1841. This increase of 50 per cent. is called a slow one by an anonymous English writer who eompares it with what took place in the next 30 years, when it increased to 8500 millions of pounds, i.e., about 100 per cent.2 In his Dictbnary of Commerce McCulloch estimates the capital invested in the cotton industry at £ 40 millions, and the profits of the manufacturers,—plus wages of superintendence, renewal of machinery and buildings, and coals—at £ 13.5 millions, or say £ 8 millions nett, while their number was, according to the same economist, about 2000. This would work out to an average profit of 20 per cent, or £ 4000 per factory. 1) There was a temporary Income Tax from 1799 to 1816. 2) The State Debt and the National Capital, p. 7. London, 1920. This increase in the capital is reflected in the deposits at the Bank of England, which rose in the same period from about 15 millions in 1845 to nearly 30 millions in 1872. R. H. Inglish Palgrave, An Analysis of the Transactions of the Bank of England. London, 1874. 84 CHAPTER VII. Religion of the Trading Classes* Though there is perhaps no domain of life where religion plays a less important röle than in business, it is curious to observe that among the pictures of merchants and manufacturers drawn in Early Victorian novels there are such a great number of Dissenters and Quakers. Abel Fletcher in John Halifax was a Quaker, likewise Carlyle's philanthropic manufacturer Friend Prudence. In Yeast we read of Lord Minchampstead's father, Mr. Obadiah Newbroom, that he was a Dissenter, while his son became a Churchman. Kingsley repeated this process in Alton Locke: Uncle Locke was a Dissenter, but he sent his son to Cambridge to qualify for the Church. In Samuel Titmarsh we make the acquaintance of John Brough, "who was a great man among the Dissenting connection," while his partner, Mr. Hoff, is described to us by Thackeray as "a young chap, very quiet and steady, of the Quaker persuasion." Mr. Tag-rag, the linen-draper in Ten thousand a Year, was also a Dissenter, while his wife is introduced to us by Warren, as she "sat reading a profitable volume, entitled "Groans from the Bottomless Pit, to Awaken Sleeping Sinners," by—as he was pleased to dignify himself—the Rev. Dismal Horror." 1 The actual state of affairs in Early Victorian times quite corresponded with the picture presented by literature. We have already observed in a previous chapter of this essay that the Established Church had lost much of its influence over the English people, owing to its tendencies towards eighteenth century liberalism and rationalism. One of the consequences of the rationalist tendencies of the Church, and of the great abuses it tolerated among its clergy, such 1) Vol. I, p. 164. 85 as non-residence and immense wealth of many bishops,1 had been the second Evangelical revival, to which we also referred in the above-mentioned chapter, and which gave rise to a renewed Sabatarian movement,2 attacked by Dickens in his Sabbath under Three Heads. Another consequence of the above circumstances, which did hardly less harm to the position of the Anglican Church, was the great increase of Dissenters of all denominations. While in 1812 there had been 4302 chapels in England, their number had increased to 8490 in 1836.* George Eliot refers to this growth of Dissent in her Scènes of Clertcal Life, where the Rev. Amos Barton is faced in his troublesome district by "the acrid Radicalism and Dissent of the handweavers." In Felix Holt the Radical there is another reference to the same phenomenon. The author says that "the gables of Dissenting chapels now—i.e., in 1832—made a visible sign of religion." She attributes the growth, not to the causes set forth above, but to the industrial revolution and "the cravings of eager men and women to reconcile themselves to their hard lives in factories and mines by the possession of religious consolation." We read how, with the advent of factories and industry in Magna Treby, chapels have been flourishing at the expense of the Established Church, and how Mr. Lyon, the Minister, confidently challenges the Rector to a public debate, a boldness no Dissenting preacher would have dared to take before the new era, and which is far removed indeed from the 1) The proportions non-residence—i.e., the practice of the incumbent of a benefice to live elsewhere—had assumed appear from the following figures published by Wright in a series of letters in the Morning Chronicle in 1813, and cited in the Black Book, vol. 1, p. 288: On 10,801 benefices selected there are only 4490 said to be resident, so that there were 6311 confessedly non-resident incumbents. Of these 6311 there were 1523 employing a resident curate, leaving 4788 with neither a resident curare nor incumbent. With reference to the wealth of many bishops the Black Book gives twenty-six "right re verend sinecurists," headed by the Archbishop of Canterbury, "drawing from the pockets of the industrious more than £ 220,000 per annum," while by way of contrast there is a list of livings given in which there are twelve not exceeding £ 10, say ten pounds per annum, and 3998 with less than £ 150 (vol. I, pp. 302, 306). 2) The first was initiated about 1800 by Wilberforce and others. 3) In the Black Book the number of places of worship of the Established Church and of the Protestant Dissenters is stated to be 11,600 and 7,634 respectively. 4) Scènes of Clertcal Life, p. 18. London, 1919. 86 Sometimes we find the two professions combined, as in the case of Isaac Nibbs (The Spendthrift) and of Levison (Henrietta Temple). In the so-called sweating-system, developing in the tailoring trade towards the middle of the century, the Jews also played a great róle, for which reason they are vehemently attacked by the author of Alton Locke, who shows us "Shechem Isaacs, that sold penknives in the streets six weeks ago, now a-riding in his own carriage, all along of turning sweater." 1 Whatever other trade a Jew may follow in literature, we may be sure that he is invariably represented in an unfavourable light. The only instance of a more favourable picture drawn of a Jewish business-man, though he still strongly reminds us of Shylock, is Isaac Levi in It is Never too Late to Mend, the man who brings about the rascal John Meadows' downfall, and assists the hero of the novel, George Fielding, in a most disinterested manner. But then this portrait was not drawn until 1856, when manners had no doubt gradually ohanged, and novelists had become more just in their treatment of Jews and Dissenters; when the times were past when a Jewish candidate standing for Parliament had to wince "beneath the cries of "Old clothes! Shylock" and various complimentary epithets," like Disraeli in 1837.2 1) Page 109. ^- 2) Monypenny, op. cit., vol. II, p. 375. 91 CHAPTER VIII. The Technical Side of Business Life* Modern readers, accustomed as they have been by the neo-classic and the naturalist schools to accurate details in works of fiction, are struck by the great defects Early Victorian novels often show in this respect. It is true that there are some domains of life in which novelists had already attained a high degree of accuracy in technical description; such departments as law and seafaring life can boast of pictures that are accurate down to the minutest details. We have already pointed out that Warren and Dickens were faithful delineators of the legal profession, while Marryafs novels enable us to reconstruct a complete picture of life at sea and English shipping a hundred years ago. But it is especially in the description of business life that Early Victorian novels show great defects in this respect. Numerous though the business people may be that play a röle in those novels, there is hardly one amongst them of whom we can closely follow the daily pursuits, either at the office or at the Exchange or elsewhere. About most of them there is a kind of unsatisfactory vagueness, not as regards their characters, but with regard to the professional side of their lives. We can best illustrate this lack of precision by citing a few specimens of business people in Dickens's works. Paul Dombey, whose proud figure fills almost the whole of the hundreds of pages in the novel bearing his name, is portrayed full length as the embodiment of cold and heartless pride. That this is pride in the glorious name and the power of the firm of Dombey and Son, is only a matter of secondary importance, however, and quite accidental: he might have been a nobleman proud of his ancient lineage and ancestral hall, and this fact would have entailed little if any change in the general features of the novel. But what 92 Dombey's daily pursuits are, how he must be straining every nerve to increase the greatness and wealth of his firm, we are not called upon to witness. It would even be hard to say what the exact nature of his business was, beyond the fact that the firm dealt in leather, and that shipping was also among its commercial pursuits. Another powerful king in the world of business Dickens has portrayed is Mr. Merdle in Little Dorrit. This personage is still infinitely more unsatisfactory from our point of view than Dombey. While we are atlowed a few glimpses of the doings at the latter's office now and then, we do not even Iearn enough of Mr. Merdle's business to make out exactly what it is. He is in fact little more than a general personification of the great mania in the "Railroadshare epoch" of 1825, to which the author alludes in his preface. The nearest approach to actual facts stated about Merdle is found in the words Pancks uses of him: "He's a man of immense resources, enormous capital—Government influence." For the rest we only meet him at home, during the splendid parties his wife gives, but we never see him at work upon his gigantic financial machinations and his famous "investments." Dickens makes it even hard for us to believe that this stupid, dull and awkward fellow should be capable of being the "greatest Forger and the greatest Thief that ever cheated the gallows." As a third instance of too great vagueness in the portraits of Dickens's business-men we may point to Ralph Nickleby, whose pursuits are described as follows: „He was not strictly speaking what you would call a merchant, neither was he a banker, nor an attorney, nor a special pleader, nor a notary." 1 It is not only a certain vagueness that may be noticed in Dickens's portraits of business-men, but he also often delights in imparting to them a kind of mysterious air, surrounding them by secrets that direct their doings, and might explain muon in those doings, if revealed to the reader. Thus we hear of certain events that happened long ago in the business of the Clennams, which are not fully revealed to us, but which have resulted in the mysterious relation between Mrs. Clennam and her faithful clerk or servant, Mr. Flintwioh, whose secret movements about the old house greatly 1) Nicholas Nickleby, ch. III, p. 3. 93 excite our curiosity. The house itself where this strange couple conducts the firm's business is as full of mystery as a romantic castle of Walter Scott. There are other novelists besides Dickens, whose business people are likewise depicted in a vague and unreal manner, often incompatible with the actual facts of mercantile life. Bulwer has tried his hand at the commercial genus in the person of Richard Crauford, whom we have already learned to know as a utilitarian.1 When describing the downfall of this rascal, we hear nothing about the exact causes of his failure; we are even left in the dark as to what kind of business he is conducting, and cannot teil for sure whether he is a money-lender, a stockbroker, or a merchant. The only glimpse we can catch of what he is actually doing at his office is that "weaving in his close and dark mind various speculations of guilt and craft, he sat among his bills and gold." 2 When Nemesis at last overtakes the rascal, the condition of affairs his downfall reveals to the world is described in the following vague, non-committal manner. when houses of the most reputed wealth and profuse splendour, whose affairs Crauford had transacted, were discovered to have been for many years utterly undermined and beggared, and only supported by the extraordinary genius of the individual by whose guilt, now no longer concealed, they were suddenly and irretrievably destroyed; when it was ascertained that for nearly the fifth part of a century, a system of villainy had been carried on throughout Europe, in a thousand different relations, without a single breath of suspicion, and yet which a single breath of suspicion could at once have arrested and exposed;" etc. etc. Of course all this is mere hoeus-pocus, utterly incompatible with even the most extraordinary events ever witnessed in the mercantile world. There are other novelists attempting to enter into details, when describing the doings of business people, but the results are frequently as doubtful as in the above instance. One of Samuel Warren's most complete pictures of a trader is that of Mr. Dudley 1) See page 42. 2) The Disowned, p. 231 94 in The Diary of a Late Physician, of whose business transactions we learn some interesting details. We are told that in a few years' time this merchant had amassed half a million by negotiating bills at tremendous discounts, and doing other similar things.1 It may be objected to this statement that it would be very doubtful, to say the least of it, for a billbroker to amass such a fortune by dealing in third-rate paper, as those bills no doubt must have been, considering that they were sold "at tremendous discounts." A sound bill may occasionally be sold at a tremendous discount, but this will only be done by people placed in the position of Mr. Mantalini, who applies to Ralph Nickleby for "demnation discount," because money is "demd scarce," and therefore consents to drop exactly one third of the nominal value.2 In another passage of the same chapter of Warren's book we read of a bill for 4000 pounds made payable by Mr. Dudley at a bank where he believed to have a sufficiënt balance to meet it. The balance appears to have been exhausted by his wife, however, who had drawn upon the account without her husband's knowledge, and a clerk comes to Mr. Dudley, who is in the country that day, to teil him that his draft has been dishonoured in the morning. To this story it may rightly be objected that in the first place the drawee was entitled to three days of grace, before his bill could suffer dishonour. Further it is highly improbable that a bill on "a king on 'Change," as the novelist calls Mr. Dudley, would be returned by his banker without the slightest warning to his cliënt. When at length Mr. Dudley becomes involved in financial difficulties, partly owing to an unfortunate attempt at loan-mongering abroad, he has to find means to meet some heavy demands at short notice. The manner in which the great merchant tries to procure the ready money required for these payments is so strange and contrary to all business principles that the reader is inclined to ask whether his senses have not entirely deserted him in his distress. He wants his clerk to call in the money advanced on somebody's property, to which the clerk replies that in that case— a foreclosure is evidently contemplated—a third of the loan will be lost. In the first place it might be argued that this mortgage 1) Vol. I, p. 409. 2) Nicholas Nickleby, ch. XXXIV. 95 The strike in question took place in the summer of say 1850.* In the middle of that year, shortly before it broke out, Thornton "had bought cotton largely," and "locked up a good deal of his capital in new and expensive rriachinery," for the execution of large orders he had on hand then. The strike prevented the completion of those orders, and Thornton had to pay heavy fines for the nonfulfilment of his contract. Now in our days a strike would generally be considered as a case of force majeure for a manufacturer, and we are inclined to believe that in those days the judges will have taken the same view. At any rate, if this was not the view held by English courts then, a manufacturer, contracting for the supply of cotton goods, under heavy penalties in case of non-delivery, could hardly be called a "prudent" man,* if he omitted to insert a clause in his contracts exempting him from all liability in the event of strikes, which were of frequent occurrence in those troublous times. However this may have been, Mr. Thornton had to pay his fine*, and his position is evidently greatly affected by them, for the fact is mentioned twice in this connection. "For many months," say till the end of that year 1850, the embarrassments caused by the strike were an óbstacle in Mr. Thornton's way, we read next.3 This must of course mean that he was hampered in his production, so that he will probably not have been able to work off his large stock of raw cotton. Then there comes "a great rise in the price of cotton," and we meet Mr. Thornton in the train on his return from Havre, where he has tried to "detect the secret" of this rise. This was in April of the next year, 1851.4 This rise must have come as a boon to the mill-owner who had large stocks of raw materials on hand, for now he could work up this cheap cotton into cloth, and sell it at a great profit proportionate to the great rise in prices. Whatever may have heen done with the purchases of 1850, they must have been 1) There is no hint in the novel as to the years in which the events narrated took place, but at the time of the strike "the windows were half open because of the heat (p. 169)." For convenience' sake we have put the strike in 1850. 2) The author calls Thornton so. 3) On page 413. 4) On page 342. 97 7 exhausted: Mrs. Gaskell tells us that in the early spring of the year 1852, which brought ruin upon the hero of the novel, "bills became due for the cotton he had purchased," and this cannot of course have been the cotton bought two years earlier, as bills with a currency of two years do not exist in business and certainly not in the cotton trade: for cotton or so-called 'American' bills three months was the rule.1 They were not even used in those days, when bills at long usance were the rule in foreign trade, owing to the slowness of transport and Communications, when months often elapsed before goods consigned across the sea could be heard of.2 We may therefore conclude that Thornton had had to lay in a fresh supply of materials after the strike, and consequently he must have benefited by the great rise of 1851 to no small extent. Nevertheless he fails in the depression of 1852. The author explains this failure by pointing among other things to the fact that his capital is locked up in machinery, and that he loses the interest on it, but this is equally incompatible with the above-mentioned fact that his mill was kept running ever since the strike of 1850. Another cause of Thornton's downfall mentioned by Mrs. Gaskell, is "the constant drain of expenses for working the business," but it is hardly more convincing than the first circumstance, and is, moreover, flatly contradictory to it, for there can only be loss of interest on machinery, when it is idle, but in that case there are no working expenses! 1) Report of the Committee of Manufactures, Commerce and Shipping of 1833, p. 91. 2) A. W. Kirkaldy, British Shipping, p. 158. It is true that we find references in literature to a longer currency even; Samuel Warren tells us of a young man's "long bills accepted payable on his reaching twenty-one;" they were not commercial bills, however, but belonged to money-lenders' practices. (The Diary of a Late Physician, vol. II p 184) In those days the usual terms of credit were fröm 3 to 6 months in' mdst trades. In the China and East India trades, since they had been thrown open to all, twelve months' bills are said to have become general, but this fact was repeatedly commented upon by various witnesses before the Secret Committee of Commercial Distress of 1848, by whom they were called bills of very long dates! M.. . There remains of course the possibility in Thornton s case tnat lus dius had been regularly renewed by the brokers during those two years. 1 his was done in some trades, such as that to the south west coast of Afnca, but in the cotton trade it was only practised by speculators. Moreover, we do not hear anything of Thornton's drafts being renewed. 98 The journey of a Darkshire cotton-spinner to Havre for the purpose of finding out the cause of a rise in the prices óf cotton is rather strange. Darkshire is Lancashire. Now the chief cotton market of the world, then as now, was Liverpool, and not Havre1 England imported about four times as much American cotton at that time as France, so that the secret of the increased prices could be cleared up much nearer to Mr. Thornton's door' As a further instance of detective knowledge of business we point out the somewhat unsatisfactory manner in which Kingsley describes a run on a bank in Yeast. Instances of such deficiënt knowledge of the technical side of business are likewise found in Charlotte Brontë's exposition of the affairs of the manufacturer Robert Moore, the hero of Shirley. As we believe to have given a sufficiënt number of proofs of what was lacking in Early Victorian novels in this respect, however, we shall not continue this enumeration. 1) M^u,.1°cn' Dictionary of Commerce, p. 454. 99 CHAPTER IX. Mercantile Clerks and Offices* Though in view of all the facts stated in the last chapter we may safely conclude that novelists had on the whole but very hazy notions about what business-men really did, it is curious to observe the general dislike, not to say aversion, shown by most personages in Early Victorian fiction to the daily work done at business offices. When Jacob Faithful is employed by his benefactor, Mr. Drummond, to keep the books of the concern posted up, he is constantly hankering to get away from the office. Born and bred on Thames barges, the young man had only been temporarily appointed as "underclerk," till a new one could be procured. His benefactor points out the very desirable situation he might have as a clerk, but in spite of all his arguments, Jacob confesses that he "could not bear it—seated nearly the whole day—perched upon a stool— turning over Dr., contra Cr "1 His clerical career ends rather abruptly after a tussle with the head or senior clerk, who tears up an invoice made out by Jacob, and when the latter refuses to write it over again, throws a dictionary at his head, whereupon our young hero knocks his superior down with a ruler and quits the office."2 In The Merchants Clerk3 Warren speaks of the "dismal drudgery" the hero had to undergo at his office, while the same dislike to clerical work is expressed even more forcibly by Frank Fairlegh, who tells us that when his father died, his mother applied to an uncle of hers, engaged in the West India trade, to procure a clerkship for hhn in a mercantile establishment. This 1) Jacob Faithful, p. 55. London, Author's Edition. 2) Md., p. 60. ..... o«: 3) The Diary of a Late Physician, vol. II, p. 26o. 100 uncle advised him to study French and bookkeeping. The young man began to study hard, so that after a few months he could "jabber French" with tolerable fluency, and worked out Doublé Entry and "other horrors of the like nature," from which he delighted to escape soon.1 From the short time it takes Frank to master all those "horrors," it appears that the author had but a vey poor opinion of the accomplishments required for the performance of office duties. Nicholas Nickleby shows even greater aptitude still, for what took Frank Fairlegh a few months, he mastered in a fortnight: at the end of two weeks he reports his proficiency in the "mysteries of bookkeeping and some other forms of mercantile account" to Tim Linkinwater, who, after a practical test in the ledger and the daybook, pronounces that the City can't produce his equal, which favourable opinion of Nicholas he chiefly bases on the fact that the latter "dots all his small i's and crosses every t as he writes it," while his capital B's and D's are exactly like Tim's own.» Indeed, we are far removed at present from such old, jog-trot business methods. At the counting-house of the Cheerybles there is not the slightest tracé of hurry and excitement, neither in the behaviour of the two charitable old gentlemen, nor in that of their old clerk and friend Tim Linkinwater. The latter "performed the minutest actions of the day and arranged the minutest articles in ttife little room, in a precise and regular order," while every article of the office requirements, down to the oldfashioned pounce-box and string-box and fire-box, had their accustomed inches of space." 9 When reading such a description of a mercantile counting house, however, we must not forget that in this matter Dickens was as much behind his time in 1838, as in a great many other things of daily life he deligthed to describe. He continued to let his personages travel in stage-coaches, when these conveyances had gradually lost all social importance with the advent of railways, and were within a few years of their complete extinction. No doubt he was likewise behindhand in the pictures he has drawn of mercantile offices and people working there. The scramble for 11 v- ï ,Sm^er/,,frank FairteSh> vol- I, pp. 166-168. Leipzig, 1864. 2) Nicholas Nickleby, pp. 199, 200 3) Ibid., p. 199. 101 money and the "blazing altar of Mammon" of which Disraeli speaks in Sybil required other methods and places of business than those we find in Dickens with his quiet and snug little nooks and corners, or his dark and dirty closets and "tanks". In all his novels we remember only one large business office arranged on modern lines, viz., that of the Anglo-Bengalee, and this was a kind of office nobody can feel much sympathy for.1 The contrast between this brilliant establishment of the swindle company, with its large staff of employees, and the old-fashioned businesses like those of the Brothers Cheeryble and Mr. Fizziwig clearly shows how Dickens regretted the advent of the new large-scale methods of the Industrial and Commercial Revolution, just as much as Kingsley did, as we have already pointed out. There is only one Early Victorian novelist who has tried to make his readers feel something of the hurry of modern business life. In Coningsby2 Disraeli introducés a personage, whose name appears to be Mr. G. O. A. Head, whose short and rapid sentences and Yankee-like talk flavour of the modern business-man. We must now make a few remarks about the clerks working at mercantile offices. There are already a rather large number of representatives of the clerical profession in Early Victorian literature, and most of them are to be found in Dickens. The usual type of clerk this author delights to portray is that of the old and faithful employee of the establishment. This type is the direct descendant of the older literary type of the faithful servant whose origin may be traced back in its various forms to one and the same prototype viz., Sancho Panza. This type, introduced into English literature by Fielding in the character of Partridge, assumed various characteristics in the later novels of SmoHett, Radcliffe, Hook, and Scott» In the latter's work there is already a specimen of the new variety of the type, the bookkeeper Owen, mainly serving his master in a clerical capacity. It was in Dickens's novels, however, that the new type was fully developed in a great many portraits, of which Scrooge's nephew, Newman Noggs at 1) See below, chapter XIX. 2) Book IV, Chapter II 3) W. Dibelius, Englische Romankunst, vol. II, p. 367. Berlin und Leipzig, 1922. 102 Ralph Nickleby's office, Tim Linkinwater, Chuffey, the old servant of Anthony Chuzzlewit, and Mr. Flintwich, Mrs. Clennam's servant and clerk, may be mentioned here. As a rule Dickens does not show us much of these servants in their clerical capacity, but chiefly uses them as a counterfoil to their employers. Sometimes the clerk even lives in his master's house, as in the case of the "little, blear-eyed, weazen-faced, ancient in a decayed black suit," called Chuffey, who sits all day long in an inner closet in Anthony Chuzzlewit's room, which he only creeps out of at meal-times, while he dozes away the long evenings in the chimney corner. Flintwich in Little Dorrit also lives permanently in his mistress's house. He is presented to us as "a little keen-eyed, crab-Iike old man," who "might from his dress, have been either a clerk or a servant." Here Dickens himself evidently feels that his clerk is merely a variety of the old type Of servant. In Marryat we find an example of a somewhat different relation between employer and employee, in Mr. Drummond and Jacob Faithful, viz., that of protector and protected, likewise a couple of literary types of long standing. In the case of the Chuzzlewits this close relation between private and business life, as it appears from the pictures of the office clerks, is further emphasized by Dickens in the description he gives us of the residence of these merchants. The "dirty, smoky, tumbledown, rotten, old house," in which the firm transacted its business, was at the same time the dwelling-house of the two partners. But business had "shouldered comfort out of doors, and jostled the domestic arrangements at every turn." The bedrooms were filled with files of old correspondence, fragments of old patterns, and odds and ends of spoiled goods, while the sitting-room, which had more office stools than chairs in it, was "a chaos of boxes and old papers," with a huge desk and an iron safe. In Samuel Warren's story The Merchants Clerk1 we find a more life-like description of an office clerk and his daily work in Early Victorian times. The hero of the story, Henry Elliott, is a young man who has had to give up his university career, and his occasional inquiries after a situation have led to the informatiOB 1) Samuel Warren, The Diary of a Late Physician. 103 that there is a vacancy for an "outer clerk" in a large City office.1 Perhaps this information has been supplied to him at a Registry Office, for, as the readers of Nicholas Nickleby remember, there were already establishments of this kind at that time, where applicants were requested to inquire within "for places and situations of all kinds."2 Elliott's life at the office was not a very easy one. Warren shows him to us, constantly on foot for two thirds of the day, running errands, and hurrying from place to place. Especially on "foreign post nights" there was a rush of work at the office; he was detained on such days, and had to slave on till nine or ten at night, "copying letters, and assisting in making entries and balancing accounts till his pen almost dropped from his weary fingers." Only an hour was allowed for dinner—then taken at noon as a rule—, but even during that short interval he was often kept at work. The salaries office clerks received for this hard work varied in Early Victorian novels from fifty or sixty pounds to ninety for an under-clerk understanding his business. Office boys are said by Dickens to earn a few shillings a week only, while senior clerks and managers of offices are spoken of as earning as much as five hundred, or even six hundred a year. The high salaries John Brough of the West Diddlesex Association paid to his twenty-four "young gents" can of course hardly be taken as a Standard for those days, as they were a reward, not for their clerical services, but for procuring clients and shareholders for the Company. The general impression we get from literature is that officeclerks, though working hard—Mr. Brough made his staff slave for ten hours a day—could not afford many luxuries. Dickens shows us the "early clerk population," pouring into the City in the morning, in one of his Sketches, entitled "Beginning business." He speaks of middle-aged men, whose salaries have by no means increased in the same proportion as their families, plodding steadily 1) An 'outer' or 'under clerk'—terms that have gone out of use now— was a clerk who had to work in the outer, or as it is now mostly called, general office, where the staff are doing their work, in contradistinction to the inner or private office, where the employers are sitting. 2) Nicholas Nickleby, p. 78. 104 along, and evidently having no money to go by bus.1 Small office boys, in receipt of seven shillings a week, "hurry along in pairs, with their first coat carefully brushed, and the white trousers of last Sunday plentifully besmeared with dust and ink." 2 In the advertisements of The Times of the Early Victorian period we hardly ever find salaries mentioned, unless in such vague terms as: "The salary will be very small, but progressive" (for a junior clerk of about 14 or 16 years old). In Business Life, an anonymouë booklet (2nd ed., 1861), there is a passage reading: "Thus we have, in the event of advertising for a clerk, even at an almost nominal salary, hundreds of applicants (p. 26)." It is also a significant fact that numerous advertisements of clerks "desirous of meeting with a situation," offer "douceurs" to those procuring them a position. In one instance in The Times newspaper we found an offer of £ 200 plus an annuity of £ 50 for a mercantile situation of £ 250 (April 8th, 1840)! Besides offices and the official exchanges as places for the transaction of business, coffeehouses have always played a great role, ever since these establishments were introduced into Western Europe from Turkey.3 Such world-famous institutions as Lloyd's Association and the London Stock Exchange owe their origin to coffeehouses where special classes of business people met for the bargaining of their transactions. The first of the institutions mentioned originated in Edward Lloyd's coffeehouse in Lower Thames Street in the second half of the seventeenth century; the Stock Exchange grew out of Jonathan's coffeehouse in Change Alley * Early Victorian novels m ention many of such meeting-places. Nadgett, the man who made the necessary inquiries for the AngloBengalee, "would sit on 'Change for hours, looking at everybody who walked in and out, and would do the like at Garraway's and other business coffee rooms." 5 In It is Never too Late to Mend we 1) Buses had made their appearance in the London streets in 1828 nf tafe was 6d. for a drive, whether a long or a short one. H. D. Traill and J. S. Mann, Social England, vol. VI p 138 2) Sketches by Boz, p. 21. 3) Kirdaldy, British Shipping. 4) A complete list of the coffeehouses in Change Alley is to be found on the map in J. B. Martin, The Grasshopper in Lombard Streetv. 190. London 1892. 5) Martin Chuzzlewit, p. 228. 105 read of Peei's Coffeehouse,1 while Dickens tells us in the Pickwick Papers that the lower class of attorneys, those of the Insolvent Court, had no office, but frequented the coffeehouses round the court'for the transaction of their business. Even political affairs were transacted in such rooms: the famous People's Charter, the first step in the great Chartist movement, was agreed to at the British Coffeehouse. 1) Page 181. 106 CHAPTER X. Peculiar Features of Business in Early Victorian Times. Notwithstanding all the detective descriptions of business transactions referred to in the preceding chapters, it should not be supposed, however, that modern readers cannot glean any accurate ideas from literature about Early Victorian business and its methods. There are many peculiarities in commerce and industry which have entirely disappeared now in the never ceasing changes of practical life, but which are still much in evidence in the literature of that period. Perhaps the most striking of all these characteristics was the prominent röle played in England's foreign trade by the West Indies. Numerous references to these colonies are to be found in novels. Ships usually sailed for the West Indies, either for trading purposes, or to the naval stations out there.1 Rich business people often made their fortunes by the West India trade, or by owning plantations there.2 In almost the only instance Dickens ever wrote a story of seafaring and colonial life, he laid the scène in the West Indies.8 At the beginning of the century Pitt still estimated that out of every pound of income for his income tax profits from abroad amounted to 7d., mainly from the West Indies.4 It is true that between 1831 and 1850 the principal exports from those islands 1) Samuel Warren, The Diary of a Late Physician, vol. I, p 407Marryat, Peter Simple, p. 327. 2) W. M. Thackeray, Barry Lyndon, p. 331. Howard, Rattlin the Reef er, vol. II, p. 71. London, 1836. In Marryafs novels the West Indian trader also figures prominently. 3) Charles Dickens, Stories and Sketches, p. 100. 4) W. H. Mallock, op. cit., p. 86. McCulloch, op. cit, p. 348. The decline was chiefly due to the exports of coffee, sugar, molasses, rum and cocoa remaming about stationary. 107 feil off by about 65 per cent., but literature, which is always slow to leave the beaten path of tradition, still adhered to the old notion that colonial trade was chiefly carried on with the West Indies. Only Disraeli's Sybil contains two references to the decayed trade of the West Indies.1 It should not be overlooked that, great though the decline may have been, those small islands still occupied the third and fourth rank in the statistics of the exports and imports of the United Kingdom for the year 1854.2 The important röle they played in English trade is further evidenced by the fact that the first docks constructed in the Port of London3 were the West India Docks, whose construction in 1802 was necessitated by the numerous thefts of the costly West Indian products.* This first enterprise was followed in 1805 by the London Doek Co., and in 1828 by the St. Katherine's Docks, both mentioned by Dickens as competing establishments in his Sketches by Boz* Being the oldest English colonies, and for a century and a half the most important, it is no wonder that in their trade with the mother country certain practices of long standing had developed. In Jacob Faithful we read of a wharfinger, Mr. Drummond,6 that later on he moved in a very different sphere, being then "a consignee of several large establishments." T This points to a form of business which was very common in those days, especially in the West India trade. It was organized as follows. The planter in the colony formed a connection with a mercantile firm in London or one of the large "outports."8 He bound himself to ship his entire erop to this particular firm, for sale on commission in the latter's market. On such consignments the English merchants advanced 1) Sybil, pp. 96, 347. i ?S1S^^d2W for the storage of timber, dates back t04)e^StBrmTLppingr p. 493. To the construction of this Doek also dates back the introdurtion* of a regular warehous.ng system, .m.tated by the Dutch "veemwezen." See McCulloch, op. cit., p. \ss>. 6) Wharfinlers ar^c^ners of riverside warehouses and of lighters for the conveyance ot merchandise to and from those warehouses . 7) This seems to have been a much used term to denote a business concern in tho'se days; confer: Frank Fairlegh Mary of aJ£ Physician, vol. II, pp. 266 and 284; Jacob Faithful. P- ,25: Mton L0CKe' p. 35. 8) English ports other than London. 108 large sums of money, to enable the planter to finance his concern while the erop was growing. As the commission usually amounted to 2y2 per cent., and the London firm, moreover, acted as buying agent for the plantation, charging the same percentage on all the stores sent out,1 we may well believe that this kind of business, which like Mr. Dudley's, was chiefly carried on in Mincing Lane, was a very profitable one. Though in the first half of the nineteenth century, with its regularly recurring speculative manias, operators mainly sought their field of activities on the Stock Exchange, either in railway shares, company promoting, or foreign loans, there are also indications in Early Victorian fiction of speculations in other domains, notably in colonial produce. This commodity was no doubt one of the most suitable for such purposes, owing to its high prices and the great fluctuations in its value during and after the Napoleonic wars. Mr. Dudley, the great merchant in Warren's Diary of a Late Physician,2 to whom we have already made many references in this essay, had a floating capital of some hundred and fifty thousand pounds outside his shipping business, and was willing to employ this large sum profitably. As soon as the "brokers" became aware of this fact—i.e., the produce brokers selling the goods for the commission houses described above—they prevailed upon him to place his capital at their disposal. Being fully conversant with the prospects of any article sold in Mincing Lane, they could easily find out which market could be "cornered," as the modern expression runs, with the best chances of success. So "the world heard of a monopoly of nutmegs" one day, while on another occasion a corner was made in atta of roses. When such a cornered commodity had been forced up to quadruple the cost, the brokers gradually put their stocks on the "gaping market," and handsome profits were realized, in which the capitalist shared. We see that everything was as nicely planned and carried through as on modern exchanges. From the fact that the author adds that "this is the scheme by which many splendid 1) McCulloch, op. cit, p. 363; Colony Trade. 2) Vol. I, p. 409. 109 fortunes have been raised," we may safely conclude that it was by no means an uncommon thing in those days.1 Generally speaking it may be said that the impression left upon the reader by the description of business transactions in Early Victorian novels is that all trading, especially to overseas countries, was of a highly speculative nature, and attended with great uncertainty.2 The very word by which overseas business was denoted points to this hazardous nature of such undertakings: the word "venture" was the usual term for them, which in this particular sense has to a great extent gone out of use* The word "speculation" was likewise a favourite term for business enterprises.* It must be added that the method generally adopted of shipping goods on consignment contained in itself a great speculative element, apart from the further uncertainties attendant upon commerce. We need not be surprised at overseas trade being denoted as "ventures" and "speculations," when we further remember the conditions under which it had be to carried on a hundred years ago, conditions which it is somewhat difficult for twentieth century 1) The anonymous author of Business Life (London, 1861, 2nd ed.) soeaks of produce speculations as a common feature of business uii his tune. He excla nS indignandy: "What is the meaning of speculating in the funds railwfy shares, hops, tallow, corn, tea, sugar, spice, and a thousand other things, where the articles were never even seen, or intended to be purchased, but simplv the dtfferences paid." (p. 103). 2) In the Report of the Select Committee of Manufactures, Commerce, and Steppin* we read that a great speculative feature of the manufactures in produff "on speculation" to wait the chance of a market_a practice denounced in Sft/V/ejJhad disappeared by 1833 (p. 46). This seems to be doubtful, however: the speculation still continued; it had only changeditenaton. STanother witness stated, a practice had greatly prevailedlof yean of making large consignments to foreign countnes (p. 35). The prevalence of This new speculative method is proved by the fact. that older Business Letter Writers are chiefly devoted to this kind of business. 3) Santo says to Antonio: „Believe me, Sr, had I such venture forth the better part of my affections would be with my hopes abroad. {The Merchaml of Venice, Act L Scène I). The oldest company incorporated hi England was called the Company of Merchants Adventurers, this being In fact the ulual designation of foreign traden. Kirkaldy observes (opat p 157): "There was but little regular or systematised trade ... Ut) was ior «ie main part carried on by a system of ventures. 4) When Mr. Dudley has purchased shares ^J^J^^^LZ in business on his own account, Warren says of him: ' In a word, he w«d on conductine his speculations with as much prudence as he undertook ttiem^ittT energy and enterprise." Anderson's MercanUe Corrfpomlenc^ (30th edition, 1890) contains numerous mstances of the «se of the term 'speculation' in this older sense, e.g. on pp. XXXI, 54, 58, 75, mó, <*c. 110 people to realize. The only way of obtaining reliable information on the state and requirements of foreign markets was to ask correspondents to give it by letters that took months and months to reach their destination, and had therefore often lost all value, when they were delivered. Market reports in the daily press suffered of course from the same circumstance, for news that is now flashed from one exchange to another in a few minutes' time, likewise took a long time to be distributed. The press did its best to serve its readers as quickly as possible, but sailing-vessels could not travel faster than the wind made them go.1 A single exchange of letters in any business transaction took an amount of time as great as the round voyage of a sailing-vessel, so that if a merchant made an offer, it might be three months or half a year, before he could expect to hear of its acceptance.2 Payments, which may now be made in one or two minutes to the remotest part of the world, had then to be made by bills at long usance, six or nine months, or even a year, which had likewise to be sent across the seas in a sailing vessel, about whose time of arrival there was little certainty.8 There is a story reported of several London firms failing for lack of ready money to meet their current engagements„ while heavy remittances were on their way to their address in sailing-vessels coming from America, but which unfortunately were detained on the Atlantic by continuous headwinds. The same speculative element of uncertainty observable in the pursuits of merchants, was likewise of great influence in industry,. and though we are not directly concerned in this essay with what is commonly called the "social problem", which had its rise in the first decades of the nineteenth century, yet we may be permitted 1) The Times of January 8th 1840 contains in its trade reports the following passages: Letters and papers have been received from Mauritius to the 16th of October last—Prices of corn at Hamburg, Jan. 2nd—A rumour was current in the course of the day that the overland mail had come to hand; it proved to be incorrect. On Wednesday April 19th we read: No news has been received from Naples of a later date than the 14th, neither is thereanything from Malta, the Levant mail being three days in arrear. 2) Steamers went faster, but were still scarce. The Directors of the Transatlantic Steamship Company announced in The Times of Jan. 8th 184T> that their (ontyf) steamer, the Liverpool, would sail from Liverpool on Jan 20th, and from New York on Feb. 20th. 3) Sir josuah Child mentions the same spaces, and complains of them A New Discourse of Trade, p. 7. London, 1693. 111 to devote a few words to it here, as the manufacturing industry formed the solid basis on which England's trade was founded, while, moreover, the manufacturer had not only to produce his góods, but also to sell them. From what Early Victorian novelists write about this department of the manufacturing industry, it would seem that the general conception about the cause of industrial depressions was over-production. Over-production, glutted markets, unsaleable stocks are the terms constantly used by novelists.1 One of the first that described an industrial crisis was Disraeli in Popanilla. His story of the Vraiblusian crisis is a satire on the light-heartedness with which manufacturers produced goods "on speculation", but it also shows us the fact that the organisation of industry and commerce was yet far from fully developed, and had not yet reached the high degree of efficiency it has attained to in our days, now that the telegraph and the telephone, together with well-informed daily and trade papers, keep every business man so well posted up about the visible and invisible supplies of materials and productions in his particular branch, that "national disasters" like the Vraiblusian are no longer to be feared on that account In Charlotte Brontë's novel Shirley the speculative methods of trade and industry are also vehemently denounced. At the first moment of prosperity, she tells us, after the Repeal of the Orders in Council merchants and manufacturers "prepared to rush into the bowels of speculation, and to delve new difficulties" for some future day. The same view is put forward by Kingsley, when he speaks of Manchester cotton spinners, "madly glutting the market in the teeth of no demand." s On page 110 we have already seen from the Report mentioned there that this form of speculation had practically disappeared at that time—which'view fully agrees with Jevon's observations cited below. 1) As Jevons observes, however, in his Investigations in Currency and Finance, this was the favourite theory to explain any slackness of trade, and "the theme of every short-sighted politician." 2) The Orders in Council were issued in 1808 as England's reply to Napoleon's Berlin Decree; the latter forbade all trade of neutral countnes ■with England, the former all trade of neutrals with France. The Orders gave rise to much friction and even a war between England and America, and were withdrawn in 1812. 3) Yeast, p. 14. 112 CHAPTER XI. Banking* The development of modern banking, which farms one of the features of the Industrial Revolution, did not of course escape the notice of novelists, when writing upon the social conditions of the country. Before proceeding to discuss what they say about banks, financiers, and the Stock Exchange, we shall first give a brief sketch of the position the banker occupied, before the great change referred to above came over England. How widely different the financial position of the country then was from what it became after the industrialization of England, is illustrated by the observation Hirst makes1 about "investment (being) a comparatively new word; it was unknown to Dr. Johnson as a f inancial term " Banks and the Stock Exchange are both the fruits of the saving and accumulation of capital, which in turn have been facilitated again to an undreamt-of extent by these same institutions. It has rightly been observed2 that it is not mere chance that in London the Stock Exchange and the Bank of England lie side by side, surrounded by numberless banks, exchange-houses, and other f inancial institutions of every conceivable kind. Both owe their rise and growth to the creation of the National Debt towards the end of the seventeenth century. 1) F.-Hirst, The Stock Exchange, p. 8. Home University Library. Johnson's definition of the term only reads: Dress; doaths; garment; hatnt. Too mach importance should not be attached to this fact, however. Johnson's Dictionary, whatever its merits may be in other respects, lacked a great number of business terms that were current long before he wrote it, e.g., 'speculator' and 'speculation', 'drawer* and 'drawee', and several others in connection with Bills of Exchange 2) Md., p. 18. 113 Before the introduction of that new method of procuring money for government purposes there was absolutely no scope for the investment of savings, unless in the purchase of land and other property, such as platè and jewellery, or by lending them to some person on his bond in the manner of Shylock.1 About the middle of the seventeenth century ibere was a general practice in London of giving such accumulated specie into the custody of one of the numerous goldsmiths in the City.2 The latter used these deposits to make loans to the King and others at high rates; at first they did not allow any interest themselves. Gradually competition compelled them to do so, however, much to the gratification of their depositors, as appears from the satisfied tone in which Samuel Pepys couched the following entry in his Diary under date of the 30th of March 1666:» "Up and after much business out to Lombard Streete, and there •received 2200 l and brought it home; and, contrary to expectation, received 35 /. for the use of 2000 /. of it [for] a quarter of a year, where it hath produced me this profit, and hath been a convenience n Sir losuah Child wrote about the old method of using cash: « before thiway of private banking came up, men who had money were often to^ it He dead by than until they could meet with securitaes Jo Sr 'ÏÏds°» and he complains that few "can be led to lay out their monTy in^land" now. NwDiscourse of Trade, c.ted by J W. Gilbart, ThfHistory, Principles, and Practice of Banking, vol. I, PP. 26, 27. London, 18Bo'th oractices of the old capitalists mentioned in the text we find ijlustrated Both practices oi ine um y November 1666 he wrote that he had m Pepys Diary. On the 12th ot N°ve™e m three thousand X,n?vl-VlT57 SndSn UB3),wnüe in another passage he tells us Ï^ÖSSStif saysS» Se the« siejiZr«^ meïha^te to keep the r cash in their own houses again, or to handl it to the in Lombard Street, p. 285. 3) Diary of Samuel Pepys, vol. IV—VI, p. 114 to me, as to care and security of my house, and demandable at two days' warning, as this hath been." This passage shows us that deposit banking had been established in London by this time. Out of it there developed, almost simultaneously, the system of keeping running accounts, or "running cashes", as they are called in the oldest London Directory extant (1677). Two documents that are of every day use now, were the natural outcome of current accounts and deposit banking, viz., the "check" and the "goldsmith's note." A "check" was an order given by the holder of a "running cash," to his goldsmith and banker, to pay a certain amount to the bearer.1 The oldest specimen extant reads as follows: Bolton, 4th March, 1684. At sight hereof pay unto Charles Duncombe Esq. or order, the sum of four hundred pounds, and place it to the accompt of Your assured triend Winchester.2 Cheques are so frequently mentioned by Early Victorian writers that it would appear that the now wide-spread English usage of keeping a banking-account had already made great progress in the first half of last century. Though it had no doubt not yet reached the dimensions of modern times, in which it is said that in English speaking countries "almost every one who is in the possession of a moderate income, say £ 300 a year, or more, has a bankaccount," 8 yet in novels we may even come across instances like that of Mr. Elliott,* whose income feil far below the above-named minimum, and who yet kept his small capital at a bank. It was especially the advent of the joint stock banks after 1834 which 1) American English has preserved this older spelling of the word 'cheque' down to the present time. 2) The G rass hopper in Lombard Street, p. 129 3) Francis Hirst, The Stock Exchange, p. II. 4) Samuel Warren, The Diary of a Late Physician, vol. II, p. 315. 115 greatly promoted the increase of this practice. Establishments like the London and Westminster and the London and County, which made it a special business to canvass customers who could only keep a balance of £ 50 or less at the bank,1 did much to inculcate the principles of banking in the minds of small tradesmen, shopkeepers, and the middle classes. However great the spread of the use of cheques may have been already at that time in London, yet there is no doubt that in the country the old goldsmith's note still formed the principal instrument, albeit under another name. The original goldsmiths' notes were simply what would now be called deposit receipts, but they were soon made use of in a manner that gave them a widely different character. With the increasing want of currency, as a consequence of the growing trade of England, they soon circulated from hand to hand, and thus came to be used as a kind of paper currency, which we may conskler as the first banknotes used in England, and the forerunners of the modern country notes, i.e., banknotes issued by other banks than the Government bank. This practice of circulating the goldsmiths' notes was greatly facilitated by the fact that since 1705 all promissory notes had been declared transferable to a third party.2 The old name of "goldsmiths' notes" is still found in Early Victorian literature in one instance, viz., in Ainsworth's story of Jack Sheppard, the notorious highwayman of the early decades of the eighteenth century. Jonathan Wild, a robber, tells his friends that in the course of his business he has become the owner of a small Dutch sloop, by means of which he can transmit to Holland or Flanders his booty, "as well as occasionally a bank or goldsmith's note which has been spoken with by way of the mail." 3 Later on we hear Wild instruct Van Galgebrok, the master of his sloop, to dispose of the goldsmith's note he had given him the 1) Nowadays London banks announce their willingness to take interestbearing deposits from I/- upwards, "in order to promote thrift." 2) J. W. Gilbart, op. cit, vol. I, p. 103. The notes soon became obtainable in fixed denominations, like Bank of England notes. 3) W. H. Ainsworth, Jack Sheppard, p. 143. Leipzig, 1846. Wild means of course that the mails had been robbed in order to obtain the note. Robbenes of mails and travellers were very frequent. Numerous episodes in literature describe such attacks by highwaymen, e.g. in Jack Sheppard, Paul Clifford, Midshipman Easy, Barry Lyndon, etc. 116 day before, as soon as he reached Rotterdam, as it would be advertised the next day.1 Two things may be inferred from these passages. In the first place it appears that goldsmiths' notes could also be cashed outside England, probably at the offices of money-changers. It further appears that in case of theft or loss the owner of a note could stop payment of it, and thus make it worthless. This fact would then be announced by the paying banker, but of course in those slow days the news would not travel so fast to Rotterdam. The practice of making the notes payable to a banker only, by means of crossing, which came into vogue for cheques in the first decades of the nineteenth century,2 could not of course be resorted to in the case of banknotes, as this would have hampered their use as paper currency too much. As most of the banking goldsmiths soon found that their banking business increased more rapidly than their sales of plate and jewellery, and was, moreover, much more profitable, they were induced to devote themselves entirely to what had originally been but a subsidiary branch of their trade, and since 1700 we may consider the two professions of 'plateworkers' and bankers to have been entirely separated.8 Thus^ arose a large number of what are called private banking houses, in contradistinction to the Bank of England, and to the joint stock banks appearing later on. The business of those private bankers included receiving money on deposit, keeping current accounts, and issuing their above-mentioned goldsmiths' notes to the public. Like the old goldsmiths before them, they also exercised the calling of money-lenders. In Swift's Journal of a Modern Lady there is a servant who informs his mistress that a goldsmith is waiting below, and says: Your dressing-case he'11 be content To take, for interest cent. per cent. The certainty that the notes of private bankers would be converted into specie on demand depended on the general financial position 1) Ibid., p. 209. J B M^rtinPTtiCcyamei67t0 towards tne end of tne eighteenth century. 1890—f' HiIt°n P"Ce' * Handbook °f Lott Peter Simpte. Leipzig, 1842. , The Pirate. Routledge and Sons, London. Marsh,, Mrs., Emilia Wyndham. Leipzig, 1852. Marshall, A., Principles of Economy. London, 1930. Martin, J. B., The Grasshopper in Lombard Street. London, 1892. Martineau, Harriet, Letters on Mesmerism. London, 1845. ( The Factory Controversy. A Warning against Meddling Legislation. Manchester, 1855. , Biographical Sketches. London, 1876. , Biography. London, 1877. 204 Martineau, James, A Discourse on Commercial Morals. London, 1856. McCulloch, J. R., A Dictionary of Commerce. London, 1845. , Treatises and. Essays. London, 1859. Mees, Mr. R., De moraal in het handelsleven. Amsterdam, 1919. Meredith, H. O., Outlines of the Economie History of England. Pitman, London. Meulen, C, Industrial fustice through Banking Reform. London, 1917. Mill, John Stuart, Autobiography. London, 1873. Monypenny, W. F., The Life of Benjamin Disraeli, Earl of Beaconsfield. London, 1912. Mortimer, Thomas, Every Man his Own Broker, or a Gnide to Exchange Alley. London, 1761. , The Nefariotts Pr actie e of Stock Jobbing. London, 1810. Morrison, C, Labour and Capital. London, 1854. Mullock, W. H., Social Reform etc. London, 1914 Multatuli, Max Havelaar. Amsterdam, 1922. Nicholl, J., Thomas Carlyle. London, 1918. Nierop, S. van, De Vennootschap met Beperkte Aansprakelijkheid volgens het Engelsche recht. Diss. Amsterdam, 1866. Palgrave's Dictionary of Poütical Economy. London, 1908. Parker, Sir Gilbert, The Land, The People, and The State. London, 1910. ParliAmenTary Réports. British Museum, (386) IV. Peacock, Thomas Love, Paper Money Lyrics. (Works, vol. III) London, 1891. , Melincourt. London, 1891. , The Misfortunes of Elphin. London, 1891. , Crotchet Castle. London, 1891. Pepys, Samuel, Diary of Samuel Pepys. London, 1923. Price, F. G. Hilton, A Handbook of London Bankers. London, 1890. Punch, volumes 1840,v 1841. Raven, C. E., Christian Socialism. London, 1920. Ravenstone, H., Thoughts on the Funding System. London, 1824. Reade, Charles, It is Never too Late to Mend. London, 1896. Report of the Committee of Manufactures, Commerce and Shipping. London, 1833. Report of the Select Committee of Commercial Distress. London, 1848. RlCARDO, David, Works. London, 1852. Ruskin, John, Unto this Last. London, 1907. Russell, Richard, Company Frauds Abolition. London, 1899. Saintsbury, George, A Short History of English Literature. London, 1905. Shakespeare, William, The Merchant of Venice. Shelley, The Diary of Frances Lady —. London, 1912. Smedley, F. E., Frank Fairlegh. Leipzig, 1864. Stamp, J. C, British Incomes and Property. London, 1916. Step hen, Leslie, The English Utilitarians. London, 1900. 205 Swift, Jonathan, The Dog and the Thief. Pastoral Dialogue. The South Sea Project. The Journal of a Modern Lady. London, 1883. Thackeray, W. M., Cox"s Diary. London, 1899. , Memoirs of Mr. C. J. Yellowplush. London, 1899. , The Fatal Boots. London, 1899. > Samuel Titmarsh. London, 1899. , Barry Lyndon. London, 1899. , Vanity Fair. London, 1899. thompson, D. G., The Philosophy of Fiction. London, 1890. Tomkins, Isaac, Thoughts upon the Aristocracy of England. London, 1835. Tönnies, Prof. Dr. F., Die Entwicklung der sozialen F rage bis zum Weltkriége. Berlin, 1919. Traill, H. D. and J. S. Mann, Social England. London, 1904. Trumble, A., In Jail with Dickens. London, 1896. Ure, Dr. Andrew, The Philosophy of Manufactures. London, 1835. Wallas, Graham, The Great Society. New York, 1920. Walpole, Sir Spencer, A History of England from the Conclusion of the Great War in 1815. London. Warren, Samuel» The Diary of a Late Physician. Leipzig, 1844. , Ten Thousand a Year. Leipzig, 1845. , Now and Then. Leipzig, 1848. Wheeler, J. F., The Stock Exchange. London, 1913. WiThers, Hartley, Stocks and Shares. London, 1917. Wordsworth, c, Law of Joint Stock Companies. London, 1842. worts, F. R., Modern Industrial History. London, 1919. 206 STELLINGEN. I. De meening, dat de politieke overtuigingen van Dickens zich tusschen 1846 en 1855 gewijzigd zouden hebben, berust op zeer zwakke gronden. II. Dickens' succes als hervormer van maatschappelijke toestanden wordt dikwijls overdreven. III. De praktische toepassing, door Carlyle in Past and Present geschetst van de beginselen neergelegd in zijn werken Sartor Resartus en Heroes, Hero-worship, and the Heroic in History, mist elke bewijskracht. IV. De hervorming der maatschappij, door Carlyle bepleit in Past and Present, zou leiden tot de grootst mogelijke willekeur en tirannie. V. Geen van de romanschrijvers uit het z.g. vroeg-Victoriaansche tijdperk verwachtte veel heil van de pogingen der arbeidersklasse, om zelf haar lot te verbeteren. VI. Als politieke en sociale roman beteekent Felix Holt, the Radical van George Eliot niet veel. VIL Het verwijt, dat Dickens den spoorweg in zijn romans pas beschrijft achttien jaar naar zijn ontstaan, is onverdiend. VIII. De beteekenis van de letter c. in den term c.i.f. wordt dikwijls Verkeerd uitgelegd. IX. De stelling, dat de Engelsche handelstaal een eigen, afzonderlijke spraakkunst bezit, is zeer overdreven. X. Manly's veronderstelling, dat in het vijfde tooneel van het vijfde bedrijf van Robert Oreene's James the Fourth de regels 31 tot en met 44 gelezen behooren te worden na regels 45 tot en met 77, is veel minder aannemelijk dan de opvatting, dat wij hier te doen hebben met twee passages, waarvan de tweede bedoeld is ter vervanging van de eerste. XI. Schrijvers van romans met een strekking dienen zich er zooveel mogelijk van te onthouden, om opzettelijk didactisch te zijn in hun werk. XII. Het woord „railroad" is niet een Amerikanisme, zooals dikwijls wordt aangenomen, doch een woord van zuiver Engelschen oorsprong. XIII. Litterair en verder algemeen ontwikkelend onderwijs zonder utiliteitsdoeleinden is onontbeerlijk aan Hoogere Handelsscholen, als noodzakelijk tegenwicht tegen het materialistischpraktische karakter van het overige onderwijs. SOME ASPECTS OF BUSINESS LIFE H. JANSONIUS SOME ASPECTS OF BUSINESS LIFE IN EARLY VICTORIAN FICTION SOME ASPECTS OF BUSINESS LIFE IN EARLY VICTORIAN FICTION. ACADEMISCH PROEFSCHRIFT TER VERKRIJGING VAN DEN GRAAD VAN DOCTOR IN DE LETTEREN EN WIJSBEGEERTE AAN DE UNIVERSITEIT VAN AMSTERDAM, OP GEZAG VAN DEN RECTOR MAGNIFICUS DR. P. RUITINGA, HOOGLEERAAR IN DE FACULTEIT DER GENEESKUNDE, IN HET OPENBAAR TE VERDEDIGEN IN DE AULA DER UNIVERSITEIT OP DONDERDAG 25 MAART 1926 DES NAMIDDAGS TE 4 UUR DOOR HERMAN JANSONIUS GEBOREN TE LEERMENS. J. MUUSSES PURMEREND — MCMXXVI TO MY WIFE. Het schrijven van deze dissertatie is voor mij een hoogst aangename taak geweest. Vooreerst heeft het mij de gelegenheid geschonken, om aan te toonen, dat ook bij de studie der handelstaal en -techniek de letterkunde een niet onbelangrijke rol kan, en zelfs dient te spelen. In de tweede plaats is het voor mij, die reeds tal van jaren bezig geweest ben met min of meer dorre lexicologische werkzaamheden, als het ware een verfrisschend geestelijk bad geweest, om een periode in de rijke Engelsche litteratuur weer eens grondig te bestudeeren. Doch wel de aangenaamste zijde van mijn werk lag in het feit, dat het mij een ongedachte gelegenheid heeft geschonken, Hooggeachte Professor Swaen, om de betrekkingen met U, tijdens Uwe Groningsche periode aangeknoopt, maar sindsdien reeds lang afgebroken, nogmaals weer te hervatten. Ik ben U zéér dankbaar voor den steun, mij bij mijn werk geschonken met dezelfde vriendelijke hulpvaardigheid, die ik reeds vroeger zoozeer in U mocht leeren waardeeren. CONTENTS* Page PREFACE xin INTRODUCTION I. MOVEMENTS OF ENGLISH THOUGHT 1 II. THE RISING MIDDLE CLASSES AND LAISSEZ-FAIRE 5 III. SOCIAL MISERY AND HUMANITARIANISM .... 16 IV. CHARACTER OF THE EARLY VICTORIAN NOVEL 26 SOME ASPECTS OF BUSINESS LIFE I. THE BENTHAMITE TYPE OF BUSINESS-MAN . . 28 II. ATTACKS ON UTILITARIANISM AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 38 III. HARD TIMES 48 IV. LAISSEZ-FAIRE 55 V. THE NEW RICH . 68 VI. LANDED PROPERTY AND CAPITAL 76 VII. RELIGION OF THE TRADING CLASSES .... 85 VIII. THE TECHNICAL SIDE OF BUSINESS LIFE ... 92 IX. MERCANTILE CLERKS AND OFFICES 100 X. PECULIAR FEATURES OF BUSINESS IN EARLY VICTORIAN TIMES 107 XI. BANKING • . . . 113 XII. THE NATIONAL DEBT AND THE STOCK EXCHANGE 127 XIII. CREDIT IN PRIVATE LIFE 138 XIV. THE LAW OF ARREST 146 XV. DEBTORS' PRISONS 154 XVI. COMPANY TRADING 163 XVII. COMPANY TRADING — THE HISTORY OF SAMUEL TITMARSH 171 XVIII. COMPANY TRADING — TEN THOUSAND A YEAR 182 XIX. COMPANY TRADING — MARTIN CHUZZLEWIT . . 190 CONCLUSION J; . 196 BIBLIOGRAPHY , ... 202 ■ PREFACE. Having for many years paid special attention to the commercial and economie stratum of the English language, which offers a wide and as yet only partly investigated object of study, we were naturally led in the direction of commercial economy, when seeking a subject for a literary thesis. Literature and commercial economy are two domains of human thought that lie as far apart as possible, and if is no doubt chiefly due to this circumstance that literary work has been so seldom investigated up to the present time by commercial economists. Authors on commercial subjects, like Hartley Withers, illustrating their statements by quotations from literature, are very scarce indeed. Another cause of the scarcity of work of this nature may be due to the fact that works of fiction have, generally speaking, little to teach to the student of economics. Men of letters, like all other artists, will as a rule feel little drawn towards commercial and industrial life and its materialistic problems, which to them must always be more or less uncongenial. The result is that their knowledge of the doings of those classes of society commonly denoted as the business community, is frequently of a superficial and Iimited, not to say defective nature. Nevertheless, we hope to show in the following pages that works of fiction offer a surprisingly large number of details that gain immensely in importance and significance, when looked at from what may be called the commercio-economic point of view. A reader with some knowledge of economics and business life will be able to fully understand the exact or deeper sense of many a passage in novels of older writers, that must necessarily escape XIII the notice of the general run of readers, owing to the fact that such passages refer to conditions in society that have entirely disappeared and been forgotten. Thus it is no exaggeration to say that books like The Christmas Carol and Hard Times can never be fully understood and appreciated by readers who have not previously acquired some knowledge of the social and economie conditions of England about the middle of last century. But if the reader of novels may profit by the study of commercial economy, students of this science may in their turn derive some benefit from literature. Every novelist has to work out his conception of the particular work of art that he wishes to produce, by using large masses of details from every-day life, and amidst all these traits and incidents, forming together the milieu of his novel, there will often be a large number of facts and observafions throwing an unexpected light upon the problems and conditions with which the commercial economist has been rendered famihar by the study of his subject. The exact influence of these on the average contemporary member of society, however, may be more strikingly brought home to him in a fictitious story than in his more serious and truthful text-books. Thus it is that the student of commerce and industry may profit by the study of literature in the same manner as an historian who will often gain a clearer and more intimate conception of some special period or person by the reading of historical novels written by competent authors, however inaccurately actual facts may in both cases sometimes be represented in such works of fiction. It thus becomes clear that both the student of literature and the commercial economist may to some extent benefit each by taking cognizance of the work done in the other's field. That the two domains of human thought, however far they may lie apart, are at present feit to be more or less closely alhed in some respects is also proved by the new branch of secondary education the Government of this country has recently introduced in the shape of the so-called "litterair-economische scholen." For the purposes of the present thesis we have restricted our investigations to what is commonly called the Early Victonan period and to which we have assigned the same limits as some other writers have fixed before, namely the third and fourth decades XIV of the nineteenth century.1 In the choice of this particular period we have been led by the following considerations. In the first place the two decades mentioned may be called the period of the birth of modern England, not only economically, but also to a smaller degree, politically. Those twenty years, which witnessed the final change from an agrarian to an industrial state, and from a more or less feudal form of government and administration to a modern democratie form, present one of the most interesting fields for the study of economists. Moreover, there is probably no other period in English history in which the sayings and doings of the business classes were so forcibly thrust upon the notice of the general public. This was due first to the struggle of the rising trading classes for political power and freedom in the rapidly industrialized state, which aroused a good deal of political controversy and passion, while in the second place it was brought about by the slavery and social misery attendant upon the newly established factory system. No less important is the second quarter of the nineteenth century from a literary point of view, for it witnessed not only the birth of modern industrial England but also that of the modern novel. Fiction had rarely before been represented in English literature by great names like those of Disraeli, Bulwer Lytton, Dickens and Thackeray. At the end of the period it had risen to the rank of serious literature, for which apologies were no longer needed.2 We have not extended our investigations to the drama, which at that time had not yet become a means of propagating social doctrines. Though it became a form of popular amusement again, as in Elizabethan times, its aims were restricted to mere entertainment, by either inspiring terror, or giving amusement both in highflown and sentimental language. It did not treat in a serious manner of the great social and economie problems of the times. Neither have we paid attention to the aspects of business life shown by Early Victorian poetry. Though in many instances poets were stirred by the practica] affairs of life — Dean Winstay advised the tailor-poet Alton Locke to choose only practical subjects for 1) L. Cazamian, Le Roman Social en Aneleterre, Introduction. Paris. 1904. 2) Though not needed, they were nevertheless still made occasionally, for instance by Mrs. Marsh in the Preface to Emilia Wyndham. XV his work, if he wished to be successful — yet their work usually dealt with political rather than social and economie problems, and was at any rate too little concerned with practical details of business life to deserve much consideration from our standpoint. Even In the department of fiction we have not aimed at exhausting all the literature produced by the more than thirty Early Victorian novelists, some of whom wrote more than thirty novels, which, as Oliver Elton observes, will no doubt never have been gone through by anybody. Our choice among this overwhelming number of books has been led chiefly by the consideration whether any given novel at first sight promised to yield useful materials for this essay or not. We finally wish to draw attention to the fact that, as the title of this thesis indicates, we have only treated a few aspects of Early Victorian business life, namely those which appeared to be most prominent in literature, and of these even several had to be left out, in order not to swell the present volume unduly. xvi INTRODUCTION. CHAPTER t Movcmcnts of English Thought. Before starting upon the subject of this thesis, we shall give a brief sketch of the general conditions of England in the period covered by it, namely 1830 till 1850. We Consider this indispensabtó, m order to come to a just appreciation of the manner in which business life is reflected in fiction, for, as a modern critic observes, "it is life which makes literature, and the type of fiction of any age is determined by the state of thought and civilization therein ... The things of contemporary interest principally occupy men's mmds." 1 Now there is certainly no period in English history, in which business and business people occupied such a prominent positron m English thought, and exercised such a predominating mfluence on the general spirit of their time as they did during the decades selected for discussion in this essay. Accordingly we shall briefly review the state of the country and its people in its different aspects, viz., the political, social, religious, and literary character of the period. In tracing the changes and movements of these various aspects of life, we cannot do better than proceed upon the well-known pnnciple of the pendulum, which is admirably worked out by Cazamian in his L'Evolution psychologique et la Liüérature anglaise, and further by keeping in view the fact that a man's hfe — and a nation's too, for the matter of that — is regulated m the main by two controlling forces, sense and sensibility, brain and heart, reason and emotion. These two contrasting forces are constantly struggling for the mastery, not only in each man's 1) D. G. Thompson, The PMlosophy of Fiction, ch. X. London, 1890. 1 1 individual life, but also in the broader sphere of that of a whole nation, as will appear from the following short historical survey. After the great lyric and dramatic period of the time of Queen Elizabeth, and the subsequent emotional outburst of Puritanism, covering together the time limited by Marlowe and Milton, a reaction set in, manifesting itself in materialistic politics, a rational religion, and a didactic and critical literature. This period of intellectualism, which may be said to have predominated English life from 1688 till 1760, finds its best representative in literature in Pope. But long before the latter's death the pendulum had already started on its opposite course. We briefly mention as most salient points of this counter-movement: Wesleyanism (1740), followed about the end of the century by Evangelicalism, and culminating in the Oxford movement of 1834; the poetry of Young, Thomson, Gray and Burns, leading us to the great Romantic outburst of 1800; the sentimentalism of Richardson's time, with' the philanthropic movements against slavery, prison abuses, and other cruelties; the philosophic reaction chiefly represented by Coleridge and Southey, preferring in their works sentiment to the cold intellectualism of their predecessors Locke and Hume, the philosophers of the Classic period. But this progressing emotional ascendancy in English thought received a serious check after the French wars, notably in the years between 1815 and 1830. Individualism, rationalism, utilitarianism, and all other aspects of the eighteenth century Aufklarung, though they had been pushed into the background by the Romantic triumph, no doubt greatly assisted therein by the ugly light the French Revolution had thrown on the consequences the Aufklarung might lead to, had not nearly breathed their last, when the Thirty Years' Peace began. There were especially two domains in which, favoured by the peculiar conditions of England at that time, they only waited to show themselves with undiminished vigour, viz., politics and economics. For many years the liberal revival had complete mastery again over the English mind, more complete perhaps than it ever had possessed in the eighteenth century. Enthusiasm was dead in people's minds, so much so that, as the above-mentioned French writer observes, one might have expected at this time a repetition of Shaftesbury's Apology of Enthusiasm 2 (1708). A kind of emotional lethargy had come over the whole nation in most domains of life. In religion this absence of emotional enthusiasm is strikingly brought home to the reader of Harriet Martineau's autobiography. This utilitarian author, of whom more will have to be said later on, was born in 1802. In telling us of her youth, she says that rehgion attracted her as an intellectual problem, and that her faith was of a reasoning, systematic nature; at the age of eighteen she read the Bible to find arguments in it for religious discussions! In politics the period of somnolent, reactionary Toryism of men of the stamp of Lord Eldon1 and the Duke of Wellington had set in, which is satirized by Peacock in The Misjortunes of Elphin, where Seythenym, the drunkard in his old Saxon castle, is the representative of this "besotted Toryism", as the author calls it2 As Brown points out," the French Revolution had caused a savage temper among the ruling classes of England, a true spirit of "hanging them all." He illustrates this mental attitude by the fact that, whereas humanitarian reforms like those we mentioned above had been advocated with good will by men belonging to all parties at the end of the eighteenth century, Samuel Romilly and the early leaders of the factory agitation did their work amidst great detraction. It hkewise showed itself in the appearance of papers and periodicals like The Anti-Jacobin and The Anti-Jacobin Review of the Giffords,' while John Halifax contains many passages and facts manifesting the same hatred and distrust of everything coming from France. The kind-hearted Mrs. Halifax behaves most unreasonably towards poor "Miss Silver", when it appears that the latter is the daughter of a notorious Jacobin. Her presence in the household iJ? The Black Book showed that Lord Eldon, the son of a coal merrhant had every reason to be satisfied with the existinc■ JE* £ ' salary as Lord Chancellor amounted to f lsSftd* tSpeakïrf the aï oVc aV°nradf t0 £ 3'°°°' ^hile further he held an "mn^nsTlega school 2) Works, vol. II, p. 109 ch3IXPL3o£nih9°6y Br°Wn' FrenCH ReWlUti0n in En^sh History, of 4r, °- !?e elder °iff0,;d Cobbett said that "he became the servile editor of Canning-s newspaper." Advice to Young Men, p 58 London! 18OT 3 further causes a violent family quarrel, when Guy and Edwin both fall in love with her. After leaving his home and country, Guy is led astray at Paris, while further all the bad characters in the novel either go to live in France or come from that country, e.g., Lord Luxmore, Gerard Vermilye and Lady Caroline. In the domain of philosophy the representatives of the hümanitarian school of thought, Coleridge and Southey, had no influence whatever in their country in the post-revolutionary period. It was the time of the rapidly increasing ascendancy of Benthamite Utilitarianism, which was forming the powerful group of Philosophical Radicals, and thereby preparing the way for its final victory, Government reform in the utilitarian sense. Thus we see everywhere the true eighteenth century spirit of enlightenment come to life again in the post-revolutionary period, after its temporary eclipse at the time of the Revolution. As with every action, however, this clear and well-regulated intellectualism also produced a reaction. From the moment circumstances favoured a revival of rationalism, emotionalism also proved that it had not entirely died out with the romantic revolutionary period. It was as the Scotch Radical wrote that is cited by Brown: "A spark was kindled at the French Revolution, which enemies of freedom think they have extinguished, but is still burning." Though these words were meant by the Scotchman to apply to political opinions only, they were no doubt of equal force with regard to other spheres of life. Indeed, the two currents of thought may be said to have existed side by side in England at that time. The higher the power of utilitarian and freethinking rationalists rose in that country, the stronger the spark of emotional and religious idealism grew, till at length this idealism was able to put a check upon unbridled liberal freedom, as we shall see in a subsequent chapter. It must be admitted, however, that in the years between 1815 and 1830 the spark was but burning very feebly. 4 CHAPTER II. The Rising Middlc Classes and Laissez-faire* After the above brief historical sketch of the movements of English thought, which has led us up to the year 1832, we shall draw in outline the general conditions of the country during the Early Victorian period. When studying these conditions, we find that all aspects of life present a great similarity in their general tendencies, which leads us to the conclusion that English minds were still divided into two great camps, confronting and opposing each other in every possible direction. The best method to adopt, when treating this matter, will therefore be to follow the idea of two contrasting tendencies again, by first discussing all the phenomena connected with the rationalist and utilitarian doctrines, and then surveying the movement of the idealistic reaction. The former of these movements found its main support in the political interests of the country, while the latter chiefly manifested itself in religion and in literature. It is most important to observe the singular coincidence between these two movements of thought on the one hand, and two parallel economie phenomena on the other hand. One of these economie phenomena was the industrial evolution and consequent commercial expansion of the period, while the other, the outcome of the first, was the appearance of the "conditionof-England" question, developing later on into what is now commonly called the social question. We shall first shortly describe the industrial evolution and its effects on the political conditions of the country, while next we shall point out how these political changes were equally due to and further developed by the predominance of Utilitarianism. The first half of the nineteenth century is separated from former 5 periods of history by changes so great that they have often been described as a revolution instead of an evolution. This does not imply, however, that the changes took place suddenly: several stages of growth had to be passed through, before English industry reached its full development and organization in the middle of last century. The fairest estimate is that this process took exactly one hundred years. The last thirty years of the eighteenth century were remarkable from a long series of most important inventions, chiefly relating to the textile industry, but also comprising many others of equal importance, of which we will only recall the following, though the list might easily be trebled: Kay's flying shuttle (1733); Watt's steam-engine (1763); Hargreave's spinning jenny (1764); Arkwright's water frame (1769); Compton's mule (1779); Cartwrighfs powerloom (1789). In the coal and iron industry, chemical sciences, earthenware and china manufacture and other branches of industry equally large strides were made. The transport by means of pack horses along worthless roads was revolutionized at last by Brindley, who conceived the idea of water transport along a network of canals that he wished to construct. The Bridgewater Canal from Manchester to Worsley was the first of this network, and in a short time the whole commercial world went "canal-mad", just as it had gone "steam-mad" twenty years before, as Boulton wrote to his friend Watt, and just as it was to go "railroad-mad" some thirty years after. Between 1790 and 1794 no fewer than 89 Canal Acts were passed by Parliament. How such a canal system was buüt up in connection with a particular industrial or mining district which it was intended to serve, is clearly set out in Felix Holt, the Radical.1 The consequence of all these changes and innovations was a gradual renovation of the whole system of industry, which was removed from the homes of the workers to some common workshop. It must be remembered, however, that this change had already set in before the inventions were made; factory life had gradually grown up by the side of the domestic system.2 A good, though somewhat belated picture of this early sort of factories — Worts 1) London, 1916, pp. 41, 118. 2) D. H. Macgregor, The Evolution of Industry, p. 39. London, 1922. 6 calls them domestic factories, while Marshall speaks of small businesses controlled by the workers themselves1—is to be found in Sybil, where we are introduced into the workshop of the monstrous "Bishop" of Wodgate, who, on the rickety second floor of a dilapidated house, exercises the calling of a locksmith, surrounded by his numerous "apprentices." Such factories were common in the early days, not only in the towns, but also in country districts, and historie remains still exist of some to them.2 Often they were established in an old barn or some other disused building, which was fitted up for the new purpose. When handtools were replaced by machinery in consequence of the inventions described, the second phase in the development of industry was reached. This also brought in its train a great geographical change, as in view of the water required to drive the new machinery factories had to be built along the rivers now. Industry was therefore shifted, chiefly to the hilly parts of Lancashire and Yorkshire, and thus a sensational growth was witnessed far from towns. This stage in the industrial development is fully described in John Halifax, where the hero's activities centre round his water-driven factory in Enderly Valley. But in their turn these mills were likewise doomed to disappear after a few decades. Industry reached its third and final stage, when a mighty rival of water power, the steam-driven engine, was brought to comparative perfection, chiefly through the untiring efforts of James Watt and his friend Boulton. The steam-engine brought again a change in the location of factory buildings: it demanded coal fuel, so that gradually—John Halifax, although introducing steam power, stayed at Enderly!—the banks of the rivers and rivulets among the northern hills were abandoned for places where coal and iron were to be found. It was in the great towns of the coal and iron districts that industry found its final resting place. Up to the time of the introduction of steam the North of England had been poor and neglected, held in contempt by the inhabitants of the southern counties with their more advanced civilization, as is still clearly perceptible from Margaret Hale's attitude in the opening chapters of North and South. 1) A. Marshall, Principles of Economy, p. 747. London, 1920. 2) F. R. Worts, Modern Industrial History, p. 40. London, 1919. 7 But now all this was rapidly changed. The North advanced with gigantic strides in every direction. Its population grew apace: from 1801 to 1830 the population of England and Wales increased by nearly two thirds, and the greatest increase took place in the North, where Birmingham, Liverpool and Manchester grew inmensely (about 75 %). There was a great shifting of the population too, a flow from the agricultural districts in the South to the manufacturing counties in the North. The miü-owners there became rich, and fortunes grew rapidly, like that of John Halifax, and many others in the beginning of the Thirty Years' Peace, who "from petty manufacturers rose to be merchant princes and cotton lords".1 The great activity and the strenuous efforts resulting in the transformation of England from an agricultural into an industrial state strangely contrast with the political inert ia of the country during the three opening decades of the nineteenth century. As we have observed already, this was the period of Eldonian Toryism of the Carlton Club. Lord Eldon in the twenty-four years of his administration did little if any legislative work, and what little he did, was chiefly done in a spirit of savage reaction. Abuses were tolerated easily, corruption was rampant in every department of government; useless survivals and absurd fictions abounded in the laws and customs of the country, and they were one of the principal incentives of Bentham's zeal for legal reform. In literature we find some allusions to these fictions. In Disraeli's story of Captain Popanilla there is a judge who explains to a prisoner he is going to try for high treason, that he will have to be introduced by fiction of law as a stealer of Camelopards. He tells the man that the Court before which he is appearing, was originally instituted solely for the prosecution of persons molesting or injuring Camelopards, and though there are no such animals any more in the country, the old-established Court has been maintained. Offenders of all kinds are first brought in praesenti regio, by charging them with Camelopard stealing, and are thereupon tried for this fictitious offence. This satire, levelled at the many non-natural interpretations of old legal formulae, non- 1) John Halifax, Gentleman, vol. II, p. 117. Leipzig, 1857. 8 senstcal though it may seem to modern readers, was even less nonsensical than actual fact, of which Dicey says that it was "strange as the most fanciful dreams of Alice in Wonderland." Thus every plaintiff in action was supposed to be a debtor to the King, who was unable to pay his debt owing to the injury or damage done to hrm by the defendant, and thus he was afforded a ground for his action. If an English sailor attacked another in say Minorca, an action could be" brought for an assault that had taken place "at Minorca, at London, in the Parish of St. Mary le Bow, in the ward of Cheap." 1 In his novel Ten Thousand a Year Samuel Warren mentions another legal fiction, namely that of "John Doe" and "Richard Roe", two much used fictitious persons in legal actions.2 At last the incongruity between the laws of the land and its rapidly changing social conditions became so enormous that a change was bound to come. It was chiefly with respect to the parliamentary franchise that the altered circumstances irresistibly tended to reforms. The abuses that had in the course of centuries cropped up in the legislative institution were almost incredible. Many populous counties in the North sent but two members to Parliament, while large towns like Manchester and Liverpool were not represented there at all. On the other hand there were numerous small places without any political or commercial hnportance, belonging entirely to some landed proprietor, and with perhaps no more than a dozen or two of voters,3 that returned their one or even two members. These were the so-called "rotten boroughs", of which Sir Courtenay Gilbert gives some interesting specimens. "At Droitwich the qualification of an elector was being "seised in fee of a small quantity of salt water arising out of a pit." It was proved before a parliamentary committee that the pit had been dried up for more than forty years. But there were title deeds which could be produced by the voter at the poll. At Downton, in 1) A. V. Dicey, The Relation between Law and Public Opinion in England in the Nineteenth Century, p. 92. London, 1914. 2) Ten Thousand a Year, vol. I, p. 256. Tauchnitz ed. 3) In Peacock's Melincourt there is a story of Rottenburgh, who has purchased "one half of the elective franchise vested in the body of Mr. Christopher Corporate, the free, fat, independent burgess of the ancient and honourable borough of Onevote, who returns two members to Parliament." Works, vol. I, p. 106. 9 Wiltshire, one of the burgage tenements was in the middle of a water course. At Old Sarum, where ploughed fields gave seven votes which returned two members, there was no building, and a tent had to be erected for the returning officer. Title deeds to qualifying property of this kind passed easily and rapidly from hand to hand, as occasion required. Hence the class of "snatchpaper voters." A woman could not vote herself, but she could pass on her qualification temporarily to any man. At Westbury a widow's qualifying tenement was worth a hundred pounds to her in 1747." 1 About one half of the seats were obtained by election, the others merely by nomination of estate owners, or by purchase. How elections used to be held under the old régime is fully described in John Halifax, where we also read of the attempted practices of what Itbert calls the "snatchpaper voters," in the borough of Kingswell.2 As appears from the example of the lucky Westbury widow, however, these practices were not new: indeed they had been carried on for centuries. As early as the Commonwealth members had already been nominated by borough owners, while seats had long been dealt in as an article of commerce, the King himself being at times a great purchaser! The reason that such things now began to be feit as intolerable abuses is the above-mentioned shifting of the population and the central seats of wealth and power to the North. Moreover a new class of men had sprung into existence there, the wealthy leaders of the industrial movement. They formed what is commonly called the new middle class, la nouvelle bourgeoisie, and knew what they were worth. "The middle, not the upper class, are the part of the nation," a pamphleteer wrote, "which is entitled to command respect, and enabled to win esteem, or challenge admiration. They read, they reflect, they reason, they think for themselves;...They are the nation, the people, in every rational or correct sense of the word. By them, through them, for them, the fabric of government is reared, continued, designed. How long are they likely to suffer 1) Sir Courtenay Ilbert, Parliament, p. 39. London, 1922. 2) Vol. II, ch. II. 10 a few persons of overgrown wealth, laughable folly, and considerable profligacy, to usurp, and exclusively to hold, all consideration, all importance?" 1 Many, if not the greater part of them, had risen from the ranks, as the novels of the period show us: Obadiah Newbroom, Carson, Hillary, Dudley, Thornton, Trafford, Halifax, Moore, Bounderby,—all of them had started life at the bottom of the ladder, and fought their way upwards. Cazamian characterizes the new race as follows: "La race des puissants du jour sort des usines et des ateliers, oü, modestes patrons, leurs pères mettaient encore la main au travail; oü des fortunes s'édifient en quelques années, oü les "lords du coton" grandissent hors des cadres surannés de la vieille aristocracie; de la Mersey et de la Tamise, oü les docks se gorgent d'infinies richesses; de la Cité, du Stock-Exchange, oü 1'agiotage fait danser aux millions leur ronde fantastique. Identiques dans leurs goüts et leurs idéés, portant également 1'empreinte des conditions économiques qui les ont produits, ces éléments divers s'agrègent et se fusionnent pour former une classe homogène, avide d'activité et de puissance." 2 It is no wonder then that, when these powerful and energetic men of business set their shoulders to the wheel, Reform was not to be put off any longer. This happened in 1830. Having described how the industrial revolution was the great cause of the Reform of 1832, we will now turn our attention to the parallel movement of intellectualism, which manifested itself in its various aspects of Benthamism, rationalism, individualism, and Philosophical Radicalism, and which, as we observed already, now showed itself with greater vigour than ever before. The leader of this school of thought was a lawyer, Jeremy Bentham, who was not so much a utilitarian moralist but a legal philosopher. He was a representative of the eighteenth century Aufklarung. His principles of law reform are currently summarized as follows3: 1. Legislation is a science. 2. Its object is the greatest 1) Thoughts upon the Aristocracy of England, by Isaac Tomkins, llth edition. London, 1835. 2) L. Cazamian, op. cit, p. 25. 3) Dicey, op. cit., p. 134. 1 11 happiness of the greatest nutnber1. 3. Everybody is best able to decide for himself what will be happiness for him. The greatest happiness principle which became the fundamental doctrine of Benthamism, has been traced back to the seventeenth century, but was at first used only by theologians, while Bentham applied it first as a criterion for good and bad laws. The third tenet contains the germs of the famous maxim of "laissez-faire" of the orthodox economists, which had been defended by them since the days of Adam Smith.2 Its object was to remove all restrictions on the free action of individuals, if they were not necessary in order to secure the same freedom to his neighbours. This principle actuated the Benthamites in their attacks on any restraint not justifiable by reasons of utility. • The group of thinkers Bentham collected round him are called the Philosophical Radicals, which name points to the fact that they were not all men of the study, like Austin, James Mill and his son John Stuart, but also active politicians propagating his ideas in Parliament, such as Hume, Roebuck, Grote, Molesworth, and others. Closely allied to the school of Bentham, and indeed frequently indentified with it, there was another intellectual movement originating in the work of Adam Smith, which also became a great force after the Revolution, namely the Economie school, whose chief representatives were Malthus, Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill. Up 1) This is an application of the "principle of utility", which in Bentham's acceptation mainly distinguished itself by the manner in which he applied it as criterion between right and wrong, to legislation first, and to morals afterwards, thus, as John Mill triumphantly expresses it in his Autobiography, "passing judgment on the common modes of reasoning deduced from phrases like law of nature, right reason, the moral sense, natural rectitude and the like." 2) This is the famous '"self-interesf' principle that has aroused so much indignation among the opponents of the school (Carlyle in the Edinborough Revtew in 1829), and which is traced back in Palgrave's Dictionary of Political Economy (vol. iii, p. 374. London, 1908) to Munn's Treasure by Foreign Trade (1664), and to a statement of Defoe's in the Mercator. Adam Smith has fully worked it out in a passage in The Wealth of Nations (vol. II, book IV, p. 35, London, 1772) where he shows that every individual, in promoting "domestick" industry, only intends his own gain, "and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand, to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest, he frequently promotes that of the society more effectively than when he really intends to promote it." 12 to the second decade of the century political economy had been a science which was scarcely known and studied except by philosophers, but since the appearance of Ricardo's Principles of Political Economy and Taxation in 1817 the new science rapidly asserted itself, as appears from the following dates: in 1818 appeared Jane Marcet's Conversattons on Political Economy, a book for the popularization of the useful science; in 1819 Ricardo took his seat in Parliament, and McCulloch takes a delight in telling us that, "being known tobe a masterof economical science, his opinion, from the moment he entered the House of Commons, was referred to on all important occasions." 1 In 1820 the Merchants of London addressed their famous Petition to Government, in which they demanded the introduction in legislation of the principles of commercial freedom, and expressed their conviction of the impolicy and injustice of the restrictive system, and the desirability of the abolition of all protective duties.2 In 1821 an Economie Club was founded in London. In 1825 followed the appointment at Oxford of a professor of Political Economy, the first in England. The theories of these Orthodox Economists, as they are frequently called from their efforts to preserve the true principles of the founder of the science, were based on the same utilitarian grounds as Benthamfsm, and from 1830 the two schools may be said to have practically merged into one. After this brief outline of the character of the two contemporary schools of thought, we need not be surprised to see that they rapidly rose to great influence in the second and third decades of the nineteenth century, when we remember that in those same years the new middle class was making a determined effort at obtaining the place in politics which was due to it by virtue of its wealth and social power. The manufacturing classes and the utilitarian economists soon feit how well they suited each other, and how great the support would be which each could give the other. The economist was pleased to see the conclusions of his science confirmed by the approval of the men of practical life, while 1) Treatises and Essays, J. R. McCulloch, p. 557. London, 1859. It may be regretted that the science has lost so much of its parliamentary influence since that time! 2) Reprinted in McCulloch's Commercial Dictionary, A New Edition, p. 384. 13 the doctrine which made individual selfishness the sole governing factor in the progress of humanity was eagerly seized upon by the middle classes as the best meansi for the advancement of their class interests. As a German writer says, "Das Ideal der Freiheif in Form des freien Wettbewerbs kam dem Interesse des Unternehmers entgegen. Es gestattete ihm, ohne alle Beschrankung durch staatliohe Gewalten nach eigenem Ermessen seine Arbeitszeiten zu veriangern, seine Löhne zu drucken ..." 1 In the sphere of politics their interests were equally served by the Benthamite doctrines: their desire for reform found a ready-made programme in Bentham's legal science on utilitarian principles. No wonder therefore that the Manchester party readily identified its aims with the small group of Philosophical Radicals. Bentham met James Mill in 1808, and the Westminster Review, the organ of the new party, was founded in 1823. It took the lead in the attacks upon the Government and in the Reform movement, and since 1830 the two schools of thought may be said to have completely coalesced. As long as Benthamism was propagated by the leaders themselves, its only object was to diminish the misery in the world: the Mills, Romilly, Grote and the others were all, like the great master himself, actuated by no other motive but philanthropy and compassion. Cazamian says of them that they possessed "une passion sincère du bien public." When the doctrine that every citizen best served the interests of the community by following his own interests, became popularized, however, in the hands of political economists like Whately, the second professor of the science at Oxford, it took the form of statements like the following, which is to be found in a text book for school use published by this author2: "It is curious to observe how through the wise and beneficent arrangement of Providence men thus do the greatest service to the public when they are thinking of nothing but their own gain." Of course such teachings were bound to degenerate into the grossest forms of social selfishness, when they were put in practice by an uncultured, coarsegrained factory owner. After the Reform of 1832 it was again the Benthamite Radicals 1) W. Dibelius, Charles Dickens, p. 45. Leipzig und Berlin, 1916. 2) Easy Letters on Money Matters, cited by Wallas, The Great Society, p. 112. New York, 1920. 14 who set to work to carry out legal reforms in accordance with their utilitarian principles, for their allies in the struggle, the Whigs and Liberals, had become more and more frightened at their own work, as it progressed, and they soon dropped back in the movement, till in 1837 Lord Russell pronounced his famous "statement of finality," which procured him the nickname of "Finality Jack," and by which he openly declared that the Reform Act was considered by his party to be the final step. 15 CHAPTER III. Social Misery and Humanitarianism. So far we have only looked at the brighter side of the condition of England in Early Victorian times. We have witnessed the triumph of factory industry, with its corollary, the great expansion of trade, and the rise of a wealthy and powerful class of citizens, and their successful struggle for a place in the sun, thereby aided materially by the strong spirit of enlightenment that sweptj away all remnants and abuses of former centuries, just as the Revolution had swept away these things in France. This triumphal march of industrialism and individualism was attended, however, with evils tnat were of much larger proportions still, and we have now come to the point where it will be necessary to show the reverse of the tnedal. Here again the observer is struck by the fact that there are two closely allied phenomena which together offer a striking parallel to the combination of industrialism and individualism, namely the social question and collectivism. The first being the cause of the second, we shall again take the social condition of England first. The pictures which are drawn by philanthropists, humanitarians, and novelists are appalling by their dark misery, and the descriptions that have been left us would almost be incredible, were it not that they are indisputably proved to be true by a mass of contemporary evidence laid down in parliamentary reports and blue books, and by the works of truthful historians and biographers like Spencer Walpole and the Hammonds. In accordance with the new Benthamite doctrines the Government ceased to interfere in everything connected with trade and industry, to supervise the conditions of labour, to regulate hours, and to insist on the payment of fair wages. It became the accepted fact now that 16 both masters and rnen had complete freedom in regard to their mutual relations, whereas under the old guild system endless regulations protected the weak against the strong. Paternal governmental supervision, which had mainly been exercised by the Justices of the Peace, was abandoned as being wholly unsuitable to the new factory industry, in some places with the common consent of masters and men, in others again in the face of the opposition of the latter. Thus we read of a strike of Scottish weavers in 1812, who appealed to a Statute of Queen Elizabeth of 1563, according to which their wages should be regulated by the magistrates. This legal question being decided in their favour, the masters refused to comply with the decision and had the leaders prosecuted under the Combination Act, in consequence of which action the Statute was repealed. The next year the apprenticeship clauses, which had also to a great extent become a dead letter1, were likewise repealed, so that it is not too much to speak with Carlyle of a complete anarchy in the labour market, which was only partly remedied by the new Combination Act of 1825, by which workmen were allowed to combine again, for the purpose of stipulating wages and other conditions of labour. This state of legal anarchy could not have come at a more inopportune moment to the labouring classes, however. It coincided with the most complete triumph of the laissez-faire principle that had ever been witnessed in any country before. Uncultured business-men of the Bounderby type fully availed themselves of the opportunity presented to them to abuse their new social power, and this led to the grossest evils. The conditions prevailing in England could only be considered as a process of demolition of the old feudal forms of society, but the renovation that had to follow was not to be expected of the orthodox economists with their free competition.2 An enormous influx of labour continually poured into the new industrial areas, partly because labour was wanted there, partly because agricultural labourers, attracted by the prospect of better wages than the nine shillings a week farmers paid them3 eagerly 1) "Not one in ten of the workmen employed in the woollen manufactory has served a regular apprenticeship; many have not been apprenticed at all ..." W. Cunningham, The Growth of English Industry and Commerce in Modern Times, p. 568, note. Cambridge, 1907. 2) J. K. Ingram, A History of Political Economy, p. 11, London 1920. 3) Sybil, Book III, Ch. XIII. 17 left their old trade, which, as we shall see later on, was in a deplorable condition. Mrs. Gaskell shows us this immigration into the industrial towns in Mary Barton: "Tom, that's Will's father, had come to Manchester, and sent word what terrible lots of work was to be had, both for lads and lasses. So father sent George first, and then work was scarce out toward Burton, where we lived, and father said I maun try and get a place. And George wrote as how wages were far higher in Manchester than Milnthorpe or Lancaster." 1 The effect of this movement was an ever increasing free labour market, which means a supply of labour waiting employment.2 Under the old system, when the "vertical" division of society still existed* in the manner in whioh we find it described in John Halifax in Enderley Valley, every workman had found employment in the mill near which he lived and wages had been the subject of individual local bargaining, but with the growing "horizontal" structure of society, and its line of general division running between capital and labour4, the men had lost all connection with special masters and workshops. The latter maintained that free markets were necessary to enable them to compete with foreign rivals, but the men, bereft of all protection, feil victims to this freedom. Besides the violent ups and downs in industry, the great financial and commercial crises by which especially the "hungry forties" were characterized5, produced much unemployment; "rucks of money" varied with great poverty. The condition of affairs in these newly settled areas and "mushroom towns" was far from satisfactory, and strongly reminds of the conditions prevailing in Klondyke or some other district after the first discovery of gold: law, order, government were almost absent at first; the streets were unpaved, unlighted; no water supply existed, as most rivers were soon polluted by industrial processes. 1) Mary Barton, p. 33. London 1906. ; . 2) F. Engels, Condition of the Working Classes in England in 1844. London, ^^.^ mg Entwicklung der sozialen Fragen bis zum Weltkriege, p. 44. Bertin, 1919. . 4) The term 'capital and labour" had already become a very current one in Early Victorian times. _ . , ... . 5) See for this H. Hyndham, Commercial Crises of the Nineteenth Century. London, 1892. 18 Dickens describes the river on which Coketown lies as running purple with ill-smelling dyes, while there was also a black canal in the town.1 As regards further details of all the social misery, and the inhuman conditions of labour in many mills and mines, we may refer the reader to works like those of Engels, the Hammonds, and Walpole.2 We pref er to follow Charlotte Brontë's example, when she says: "Child-torturers, slave masters and drivers, I consign to the hands of jailers; the novelist may be excused from sullying his pages with the records of his (sic!) deeds." 8 It is small wonder that the conditions described above had a great influence upon the political history of the period. The Reform of 1832 had stirred up great popular enthusiasm, at which the reformers themselves had become greatly frightened. Trade Unionism, rendered possible by the Combination Act of 1825, entered upon its revolutionary period, when the Reform Act, after exciting foolish hopes of social betterment in the breasts of the working classes— Samuel Warren calls it "an Act for giving Everybody Everything" 4 —did not realize any of their expectations, but turned out to be a purely middle class measure in which the masses were left out in the cold, and none of their grievances redressed. This led to a continuation of the popular movement, chiefly aiming as a first step at the enfranchisement of the people. In 1838 the Working Men's Association in London drew up a famous program of popular wishes, which was called the Charter, and which claimed various political reforms. This Chartist movement, of which we find a full description in Mary Barton, and a still fuller one in Alton Locke, continued all through the hungry forties, often leading to violences, as Disraeli shows us in Sybil, and at last died out in 1848, when the labouring classes had gradually learned to see that Trade-Unionism and co-operative efforts would be productive of more beneficial results than political agitation. Having given a short survey of the many evils produced by the 1) Hard Times, p. 26. London 1902. 2) J. L. and Barbara Hammond, Lord Shaftesbury. London, 1923 Sir Spencer Walpole, A History of England etc, vol. IV. London 1890. 3) Shirley, p. 65. London, 1914. 4) Ten Thousand a Year, vol. III, Ch. I. 19 industrial evolution, we shall now tracé the progress of the philanthropic movement which was the immediate outcome of the misery of the masses. Properly speaking the term philanthropism only denotes one of the phases of a new tendency of the English mind, which was an emotional reaction against the cold, selfish, and rational individualism that was ruling uppermost. The social repentance or interventionism of which Cazamian speaks was the most characteristic and most active form that the movement took at the outset. Idealism, humanitarian and religious emotion, moral principles, enthusiasm, pity, altruism, all these factors go to make up the new mental attitude which rises spontaneously against harren materialism, selfishness, and a mistaken sense of liberty. Selfish individualism henceforth found itself confronted by altruistic collectivism in almost every department of social life. The new spirit of social combination and co-operation, and of mutual support for common social ends manifested itself in Trade Unionism, Co-operative Societies, Friendly Societies, and Federations of Unions. The same tendency of collectivist effort is manifested in joint stock trading and trusts, but it is of a quite different nature from the collectivism in the sense of social brotherhood which we are speaking of. Such phenomena are indeed the very opposite of socialistic in their tendencies, whatever their ultimate development may be. Curious though such a coincidence may be, it is perhaps best to simply consider it as such.1 The best manner to show the difference between the two hostile bodies of thought now confronting each other is perhaps to quote a representative passage from a leading writer of each school. Individualism we shall illustrate by a specimen of the opinions held by W. R. Greg, a utilitarian critic of great reputation. "They (i. e. certain classes of the poor) have made for themselves the hard bed they lie on. They have sinned, against the plainest laws of nature, and must be left to the corrective which nature has in that case made and provided;—a corrective which is certain to operate in the end, if only we do not step in to counteract it by regulations dictated by plausible and pardonable, but shallow and short-sighted humanity ... Nor can it be said that, in contending 1) D. H. Macgregor, op. cit, p. 46. See also Dicey, op. cit, on this phenomenon. 20 that improvidence, idleness, dissipation, and early marriages should be allowed to encounter their natural fruit and salutary punishment among the poor, we are guilty of any partiality or special harshness. We demand no more from them than from all other classes. Privation and wretchedness are the allotted consequences and correctives of these vices in all other ranks,—why should the lowest be exempted from the common law." 1 We add the following passage also representing a voice from the same camp: "It appears to me that those educational philanthropists who disdain to study the science of human nature, as it is expounded in the Gospel, have been running at fault spending their substance for a shadow. The first and great lesson ... is that man must expect his chief happiness, not in the present, but in a future state of existence. He alone who acts on this principle will possess his mind in peace under every sublunary vicissitude, and will not care to scramble with feverish envy or angry contention for the idle phantoms which the dupes of pleasure and ambition pursue Where then shall mankind find this transforming power?—in the cross of Christ. It is the sacrifice which removes the guilt of sin; it is the motive which removes the love of sin; it mortifies sin by showing its turpitude to be indelible except by such an awful expiation; it atones for disobedience; it excites to obedience; it purchases strength for obedience; it makes obedience practicable; it makes it acceptable; it makes it in a manner unavoidable, for it constrains it; it is finally, not only the motive to obedience, but the pattern." 2 After hearing the voice of this preacher of obedience,—obedience to which the poor have to be educated according to his views—we shall listen to another preacher, not to, but for the poor: "But gentlemen, gentlemen, dealing with other men like me, begin at the right end. Give us, in mercy, better homes, when we're a-lying in our cradles; give us better food, when we're a-working for our lives; give us kinder laws to bring us back, when we're a-going wrong; and don't set Jail, Jail, Jail, afore us, everywhere we turn. 1) R. W. Greg, Mistaken Aims and Attainable Ideals of the Artizan Class, pp. 102, 103. London, 1876. 2) A. Ure, The Philosophy of Manufactures, p. 423. London, 1835. 21 There an't a condescension you can show the labourer that he won't take, as ready and as grateful as a man can be; for he has a patiënt, peaceful, willing heart. But you must put his rightful spirit in him first; for whether he's a wreek and ruin such as me, or is like one of them that stand here now, his spirit is divided from you at this time. Bring it back, gentlefolks, bring it back! Bring it back before the day comes when even his Bible changes in his altered mind, and the words seem to him to read, as they have sometimes read in my own eyes—in Jail: "Whither thou goest, I can Not go; where thou lodgest, I do Not lodge; thy people are Not my people, nor thy God my God!" 1 Finally we will add a passage from Carlyle, which gives a significant reply to Ure's gospel of obedience: 4'Fancy a man, moreover, recommending his fellowmen to believe in God, that so Chartism might abate, and the Manchester operatives be got to spin peaceably! The idea is more distracted than any placard pole seen hitherto in a public thoroughfare of men. My friend, if ever thou do come to believe in God, thou wilt find all Chartism, Manchester riot, Parliamentary incompetence, Ministries of Windbag, and the wildest Social Dissolutions, and the burning up of this entire Planet, a most small matter in comparison." 2 The new spirit manifested itself in almost every dotnain of human thought. As we have said, one of the clearest manifestations is to be found in the so-called philanthropic movement. The harshness of the new social doctrines, and the misery attending the industrialization of England aroused in the breasts of emotional natures a slowly rising wave of pity for the poor and unprotected sufferers. People became alarmed at the growing degradation and anarchy in industrial centres. They began to ask themselves whether it was indeed true what the orthodox economists taught about all this misery lying in the nature of things; whether absolute free competition was the only solution for economie problems; whether man was not really "his brother's keeper". As early as 1802 the Health and Morals Act was passed, a first attempt at factory legislation. In 1806 the slave trade was prohibited. In 1811 the Philanthropist was founded, a periodical published by 1) Charles Dickens, The Chimes. 2) Past and Present, p. 218. London. 1919. 22 a group of religious persons, but among whose contributors James Mill was found, as well as Jeremy Bentham himself. In 1816 another Factory Act was passed, while in 1825 slavery was abolished. In 1833, 1844, and 1850 further Factory Acts followed, chiefly through the unwearying efforts of Lord Ashley, a great and typical leader of the "factory movement", who devoted his whole life (1801-1885) to the cause of the poor, a man who one night presided over a meeting of four hundred thieves in the darkest part of London, to study their condition and desires.1 This noble Tory belonged to the Evangelical party, which may be said to have had the greatest influence on the factory movement and on the emotional revival in general. The Evangelists were originally those members of the Established Church who, though fully sympathizing with Wesley, had not followed the latter, when he left that Church in 1739. A second movement of a similar nature has been dated at 1797,2 and this "second Evangelical Revival" became of great importance, owing to the fact that it made so many converts among the higher classes. Though at first this process had been a slow one, in the Waterloo generation "county families capitulated wholesale." 3 These Evangelists were all unwearying in their advocacy of humane reforms. No wonder, therefore, that these Tory philanthropists, when turning their attention to industrial towns, opened a crusade against the conditions prevailing there, under the leadership of Ashley, therein assisted by other humanitarian Tories, like Southey, Sadler, Ostler, and Seely. It was not only in politics and religion, but also in philosophy that the new spirit showed itself, and here it is the name of Coleridge that is most prominent, upon whom the epithet of a great seminal mind was bestowed by no less a person than John Mill. His views were chiefly propagated through the medium of The Friend (1809—10), his Lay Sermons (1816), and his Constitution of State and Church (1830). His views about the last-named institutions were directly opposed to those of the liberal individualists. The contrast between the two standpoints, which might be denoted as positive and negative, 1) J. L. and Barbara Hammond, op. cit., p. 254. 2) P. A. Brown, op. cit., ch. IX. 3) Ibid. 23 is beautifully illustrated by the following passage from one of the Critical Essays of Macaulay, a Whig of rising importance, who is characterized by an eminent critic of literature as "the very incarnation of the prevailing character of Englishmen between Waterloo and the Mutiny." 1 Macaulay then tells his readers of Sou they that "he conceives that the business of the Magistrate is not merely to see that the persons and the property of the people are secure from attack, but that he ought to be a Jack-of-all-trades, architect, engineer, schoolmaster, theologian, a Lady Bountiful in every parish, a Paul Piy in every house, spying, eaves-dropping, relieving, admonishing, spending our money for us, and choosing our opinions for us, ..." 2 The interventionist idea, which Macaulay wishes to ridicule here, and of which Coleridge was the first propagator, aimed of course at much higher ideals than to be a Lady Bountiful or Paul Pry. The Coleridgeans wished to make the State into a living organism again; not merely a negative principle of non-in te rference, but an active force for the moral and material well-being of its subjects, and for the poor in the first place. The clergy and the landed aristocracy were to be the powerful allies in the fulfilment of these duties. In this respect Coleridge may be considered as the direct precursor of Young Englandism, which likewise aimed at the restoration of the powers of Nobility and Church with the same object. Even the creed of the individualist camp, the "dismal science" of the orthodox economists, underwent the all pervading influence of emotional collectivism. The change was first introduced in this domain from abroad. Comte, the father of the historical school of economics, propagated in his French work La Philosophie positive the idea of an ordered change, and of historical comparison as a means to find the laws of evolution governing the changes in society. Thus he completed the science and to the combined social statics and social dynamics he gave the name of sociology.8 Comte's second great merit is that he infused the barren materialism of the orthodox 1) Saintsbury, op. cit., p. 713. 2) T. B. Macaulay. Southey's Colloquies on Society. Critical and Historical Essays, p. 170. London, 1870. 3) R. Eisler, Sociologie, p. VIII. Amsterdam, 1911. 24 followers of Adam Smith with moral notions, opposing social duties to individual rights. Other causes that aided to effect a change in political economy were in the first place the growing influence of socialist doctrines, which was openly recognized by no less a person than John Stuart Mill, and next the general trend science took in the Early Victorian period. The great ascendancy of the mathematico-physical branches during the first decades of the century, which is still clearly perceptible in many novels of the second quarter1, gradually gave way to a pronounced tendency for biological studies teaching that scientific laws are as much subject to evolution and change as the subject matter of science itself. The great representative of this new principle of evolution is Charles Darwin. It influenced political economy, as well as a great many other spheres of human thought, e.g., that of politics, where its effect is illustrated by the appearance of books like Bagehot's Physics and Politics, in which the principles of Darwinism are applied to the problem of political changes. 1) See below, Chapter XVIII. 25 CHAPTER IV. The Novel about 1830. Having briefly outlined the various schools of thought predominating in Early Victorian England, we shall now wind up our introductory remarks by some observations on the general features characterizing the English novel about the year 1830. After the glorious outburst of Romanticism, which had been slowly preparing its final triumph in the teeth of eighteenth century liberal enlightenment, a period of exhaustion became apparent in literature, which is by most critics considered to coincide with the fourth decade of the century, though they do not all agree as to the exact limits to be assigned to the period of depression.1 In accordance with the principle of evolution exposed in his book L'Evolutbn psychologique et la Littérature anglaise, Cazamian attributes the waning of the romantic fervour to the common psychological phenomenon described by him as "une oscillation du rhythme psychologique." The romantic excesses had provoked a reaction, a desire for refreshment and novel sensations, a longing for a change. This impulse from within was aided by various other factors, chief of which were: the social conditions of England; intellectualism, which increased in strength with the rise of industry; a kind of feeble reaction against the novelists of the "silver fork" school; the creation of a large class of novel readers among the new middle classes; new forms adopted by the book trade, by the issue of novels in serial form, coinciding with the appearance of numerous reviews and other periodicals which superseded the older and more expensive "three-deckers". 1) See Traill and Mann, Social England, p. 64. London, 1896. Saintsbury, op. cit., p. 740. 26 All these factors did two things: they stimulated the appearance of the social novel, and they determined its literary character. This last statement requires some elucidation. Two distinct features characterize the novel of this time: its romanticism and its realism. The first is a direct continuation of the preceding romantic movement, while the second is, as we have just seen, a reaction against this movement, so that the circumstances naturally favoured the appearance of what has been called the "novel-romance". Romanticism received a fresh impulse, after its apparent -exhaustion during the ebb-tide period, from the great problems that were stirring the English minds at that time, such as the condition-ofEngland question, and from the wave of humanitarianism and Evangelicalism that was sweeping over the country. In the course of the Victorian period it gradually disappeared from the novel, however, owing to the growing power of realism, favoured by the scientific spirit of the age. The combined influence of the two tendencies, the adventurous and the rational spirit of enquiry into every phenomenon of daily life, produced together what Cazamian has styled "le romantisme social," in contradistinction to the pure romanticism of the opening years of the century. Of this social romanticism the social novel has been the direct outcome, and though not exclusively concerned with this form of fiction, yet it will appear that it forms the main source of this essay, while further it should be borne in mind that many Early Victorian novels, though not purely social, contain a certain admixture of the social element, which has likewise made them valuable objects of study for our purpose. 27 SOME ASPECTS OF EARLY VICTORIAN BUSINESS LIFE. CHAPTER I. The Benthamite Type of Business~man. When investigating the attitude of Early Victorian literature towards the world of trade and industry, we must constantly keep in view the existence of the two hostile bodies of thought whose origin and ideals we have sketched in the preceding chapters of this book: one favoured by and in turn favouring the unshackled freedom of industrial development, usually denoted as the industrial revolution, and the other, being a reaction against the first, called forth by the social misery this had produced, but which, at the time of which we are writing, had not yet been formulated into so complete a system as its opponent. The trading interests were of course all to be found in the camp that propagated teachings which cannot be denoted by a more suitable name than the gospel of the rising middle classes, a mixture of Utilitarianism and Orthodox Economy. Carlyle in his pithy language speaks of "all this Mammon-Gospel, of Supply-andDemand, Competition, Laissez-faire, and Devil take the Hindmost." The close relation between the middle classes and the utilitarian economists is commented upon by the German socialist Engels in the following words: "Political Economy, the Science of Wealth, is the favourite study of these bartering Jews (i.e., the middle classes). Every one of them is a Political Economist." Novelists held the same view of the matter. Mrs. Gaskell confesses in her preface to Mary Barton that she "knows nothing of Political Economy or the theories of trade." Charles Kingsley speaks in Alton Locke of a member of Parliament, who "was reputed a philosopher, and a political economist, and a liberal," thereby showing that the rising 28 on, merely in order to furnish herself with arguments. She believes that "a little more of the cheerful tenderness which was in those days thought bad for children, would have saved (her) from (her) worst faults and from a world of suffering." Her religion "took the character of (her) mind, and it was harsh, severe, and mournful accordingly." 1 James Mill, the real leader of the Utilitarians, is described to us by his son as follows: "Temperance was with him the central point of educational precept. He thought human life a poor thing at best, after the freshness of youth and of unsatisfied curiosity had gone by ... He rated intellectual enjoyment above all others. For passionate emotions of all sorts he professed the greatest contempt, regarding them as a form of madness ... The great stress laid upon feeling was an abberration of modern times." As Stephen observes,2 he seemed to regard life as a series of arguments, in which people were to be constrained by logic, not persuaded by sympathy. The Spartan manner in which this Scotchman educated his son John Stuart8 is the exact counterpart in actual life of the domestic relations Mrs. Gaskell describes in the Thornton household, "where a stranger might have gOne away, and thought that he had never seen such frigid indifference of demeanour between such near relations." * Mrs. Gaskell's friend Charlotte Brontë has likewise given us a full-length portrait of the Benthamite type of business-man in the person of the mill-owner Robert Moore, of whom we are told that he possessed "a hard spirit, a determined cast of mind, scorn of low enemies", and further that he "refused to truckle to the mob, and was of an inflexible nature, proud to his workmen, believing that he fulfilled his whole duty to them only be treating them justly." "Forward" was the device stamped upon his soul, and he pushed his interests to the exclusion of philanthropic consideration for general interests. The third great female novelist of the Victorian era, George Elliot, has likewise tried her hand at this type of mercantile character in the person of Harold Transome in Felix Holt. Of this Smyrna merchant and banker we read that he possesses rapidity, decision, indifference 1) Autobiography, pp. 11, 95, 103. Biographical Sketches, London, 1876. 2) Op. cit, vol. II, p. 39. 3) Autobiography by John Stuart Mill, pp. 4, 34, 52, 53. London, 1873. 4) North and South, p. 207. 32 the same opinion as Bulwer about the dangers of his doctrines, a fact which is said to have puzzled the philosopher very much.1 This seems to be a little naive, when we remember that the great teacher himself never succeeded in forming a clear conception of the way in which the interests of the community could be served by individuals seeking to serve their own interests.* There is another passage in The Disowned, where a person advocates a similar mistaken or rather morally distorted utilitarianism. A great rascal, Crauford by name, and a merchant by trade, tries to corrupt one Olendover, a high^minded person finding himself on the brink of starvation, by telling him some fictitious story of a poor devil of a clerk who had defrauded his employer. Crauford defends the man's conduct as follows: "Public law is instituted for public happiness. Now if mine and my children's happiness is infinitely more served by this comparatively petty fraud, than my employer's is advanced by my abstaining from it, why the origin of law itself allows me to do it." The subtle seducer winds up by saying: "What say you to that, Glendover? It is something in your Utilitarian, or as you term it, Epicurean principle, is it not?" * In a subsequent conversation with his victim Crauford argues that in spite of religion, morality and wisdom, "there is in all creation but one evident law—self-preservation." He then proceeds to apply this Benthamite principle to his own rascally schemes again. By quoting such specious, quasiBenthamite arguments, Bulwer clearly proves that, whatever may have been his own inclinations towards Bentham's teachings, he did not suffer his moral views to be distorted into self-interest principles, but repeatedly drew his readers' attention to the dangerous use ambitious men of the world or unscrupulous Mammonists might make of them. The hatred of political economy, which is so often betrayed by writers of the Early Victorian period, is also strongly evident in 1) Oraham Wallas, op. cit, p. 108. Leslie Stephen, The Engttsh Utilitarians, vol. I, p. 188. 2) Lesli Stephen,' op. cit., p. 313. 3) The Disowned, p. 240. Leipzig, 1842. The Epicurean Standard of morals resembled that of the Utilitarians, in that it also took the tendency of human action to produce either pain of pleasure as the exdusive test of right or wrong (J- S. Mill, Autobiography, p. 48). 42 CHAPTER III. Hard Times» The most violent and sustained attack made by Dickens upon the rationalist spirit in the hostile camp is to be found in Hard Times, where Gradgrind is the embodiment of the Benthamite type as he fancied he saw it leading England to spiritual destruction, while Gradgrind's friend Bounderby is a satire on the hard-hearted mill-owner who, though in his ignorance he has probably never heard of Bentham's principle of self-interest, nevertheless carries it into execution in the most complete manner. The whole novel is permeated, and in the opinion of most readers and critics spoiled, by the author's hostile attitude towards the spirit of industrialized England. How violent Dickens's attack on industrialism and individualism is, is best measured by the reply the novel provoked from Miss Martineau, who spoke of "the work of busy and shallow minds," though she herself had considerably altered her views on the social problem since the early days of her career, when she published her Illustrations of Political Economy, while books like Mary Barton and North and South, though the solutions suggested there are not in the spirit of classical economists either, did not draw her out of her tent.1 The fact is that Hard Times attacked, not so much the practical state of affairs in England, but rather the spirit of which those conditions were the material reflection. Dickens's aim was to hold 1) The Factory Controversy; a warning against meddling legislation, by Harriet Martineau. Manchester, 1855. Her attacks are directed against Horner, the factory inspector, and "Mr. Dickens, the Editor (of Household Words)," the latter for what he attempted in Oliver Twist, Hard Times, and especially in his articles on the question of Factory Legislation in Household Words in 1855. 48 up to public scorn and contempt the secret moral springs which brought the world to moral and material ruin. These springs were of course the barren, dead, and deadening feelings of rationalism and materialism accompanying the industrial revolution, which feelings Dickens saw embodied in the teachings of political economists. The latter on the other hand considered their teachings as "merely benevolence under the guidance of science," as Greg expressed it. It may be doubted whether Dickens had studied the "dismal science" himself to any great extent. The allusions he makes to its tenets in Hard Times are vague and chiefly limited to the "facts and figures" with which it prided itself to support those tenets. These facts and figures, varied here to "averages and figures", are a mere repetition of those of Mr. Filer, and there is not the slightest advance or change traceable in Dickens's attitude, though eleven years had elapsed since he created that embodiment of statistics; The changes that were coming over political economy, as appearing for instance from the condensed translation of the works of Comte, the father of the historical school of economy, by Harriet Martineau, at one time one of the greatest supporters of the orthodox school; and from the works of John Stuart Mill, which gradually drifted away from the old "greatest happiness" principle, and showed the growing influence of the collectivist idea,1—all these changes had as it seemed, escaped the novelist's notice.2 To Dickens political economy was still the same rationalist science based on utilitarian happiness, and deriving its lessons from cold facts and figures only, to the exclusion of any other factors like fancy, feelings, art,—even though represented only by the horse-riders, or by the figures of horses in a floor-carpet, or by a sunbeam falling on Sissy Jupe's hair, or by the cow with the crumpled horn who tossed the dog, etc. 1) Oliver Elton describes Mill's book on Utilitarianism as a failure which was bound to be one, as it was impossible to find what the author proposed to find, namely an inducement, on Benthamite principles, for practising the altruism preached by Comte. Op cit., vol. I, p. 60. 2) The time was drawing near of which Jevons wrote that "it (was) evident then that a spirit of very active criticism (was) spreading, which (could) hardly fail to overcome in the end the prestige of the old false doctrines," and though he confesses that he does not yet see what is to be put in place of them, he expects "the rise of a science of the development of economie forms and relations." Preface to the second edition (1879) of The Theory of Political Economy by W. Stanley Jevons. London, 1911. 49 Another objection that might be made to this attack upon utilitarian! economy is that it was somewhat belated in view of the altered social conditions in England in 1855. The hungry forties had been left behind; since the middle of the century the country had entered upon a new period in its social and political affairs. Chartism and political labour agitation were dead; the working classes had begun to turn their attention to peaceful unionism, and other practical schemes for the obtainment of greater social welfare, such as cooperation, friendly societies, clubs, etc. Besides a defective knowledge of the progress made by political economy, there may have been the well-known psychological truth that a man's beliefs and opinions are chiefly formed before his thirtieth year, which made Dickens persist in his "facts and figures" theory; it is this same quality of the human mind which, as Disraeli observes, causes predominant opinions to be generally those of the generation that is vanishing.1 Thus is was predicted of Adam Smith that he would persuade the then living generation, and would govern the next, while Benthamism flourished in English politics from the Reform year 1832, which was also that of the leader's death. Dickens appears to have been especially subject to this tenacity of his youthful impressions and opinions, which gave a kind of conservative character to the choice of his subjects. He knew only one town intimately, London with its lower and lower middle classes, as he had learned to know and to love it in the days of the stage coaches and their never-to-be-forgotten drivers, and postboys, and passengere, both inside and out. But when, as in Hard Times, he ventured into an industrial town of the North, with its widely different problems, and the new habits of thought and character of its inhabitants, the reader soon perceives that it was wellnigh a closed book to him, as it must be to anybody that has not, like Mrs. Gaskell, lived and worked in such a manufacturing centre for a considerable time, in periods» of ups as well as of downs. Dickens must have feit this, when he resolved to go and see a strike that was on just then at Preston. How sadly the author failed to penetrate below the surface is evident, not only from the letter he wrote to a friend while there,2 but also from the fact that he went to see 1) Sybil, or the Two Nations, p. 359. 2) John Forster, The Life of Charles Dickens, vol. II, p. 86. London. 50 Hamlet at the theatre in the evening, instead of collecting materials for his novel by mixing with the crowds reading the placards at the street corners, listening to their conversation, or talking to them in order to draw them out and ascertain their views about the strike.1 The mere fact that Dickens waited so many years before treating the social question in his novels is in itself already a proof that he feit a little shy about it. He must have feit that the subject lay somewhat outside the range of his great powers. Else it will be difficult to account for) the fact that the novelist who perhaps possessed the strongest social sympathies for his fellow-men of all English authors, and who attacked every social abuse of his time -—Crotch divides them into no fewer than seven classes!2—hesitated ten years after the appearance of Coningsby, before he tackled the greatest of all those abuses. The success achieved in Hard Times falls, as was to be expected, far below the great powers he showed on other occasions. The manufacturing and mercantile classes are represented by two fine specimens of humanity, Gradgrind and Bounderby. Neither of them, however, is shown to us in his proper sphere of action, working in his mill or warehouse, absorbed in money-making pursuits, or struggling against obstacles, material as well as human. Gradgrind has already retired from his hardware business, before we make his acquaintance, and as for Bounderby, there is hardly a single passage in the book showing him in his relation to his employees. The best description, and the most complete too, is that which refers to his domestic life, and especially his behaviour towards Mrs. Sparsitt, of whom the blustering bully is secretly afraid, probably on account of her being "highly connected." But this human caricature, beautiful as it may be from a literary point of view, tells us very little about trade and industry. Bounderby is rich, and we are told that like so many business-men of the period, 1) There is doubtless much truth in Harriet Martineau's words in her pamphlet on the Factory Controversy (p. 36): ("An) effectual security against its doing any mischief is that the Tale, in its characters, conversations, and incidents, is so unlike life—so unlike Lancashire or English Me,—that it is deprived of its influence. Master and man are as unlike life in England, at present, as Ogre and Tom Thumb: and the result of the choice of subject is simply that the charm of an ideal creation is foregone whüe nothing is gained in its stead." 2) W. Walter Crotch, Charles Dickens, Social Reformen London, 1913 51 because they are for ever changing and uncertain. God has also made some weak; not in any one way, but in all. One is weak in body, another in mind, another in steadiness of purpose, a fourth can't teil right from wrong, and so on The fault of the orthodox economists starting their reasonings from a homo oeconomicus who was supposed invariably to adopt the same course of action under the same circumstances, could not have been more clearly pointed out than by this old spinner. It was the same objection all humanitarian writers made against the science. Ruskin expressed it as follows in his Unto this Last: "(Man being) an engine whose motive power is a Soul, the force of this very peculiar agent, as an unknown quantity, enters into all the political economist's equations, without his knowledge, and falsifies every one of their results." 1 Though Charles Kingsley is also vehement in denouncing political economists, who can only prove that social misery is as inevitable as all other laws of nature,2 it is yet curknis to observe that, when he is forgetting for a moment that they are the greatest obstacles to his socialist reforms he speaks of them in a surprisingly laudatory manner, as being expert advisers in the execution of a plan for a co-operative farm,3 while in another passage in the same book he writes that his readers have no doubt read more wisdom than they have practised yet, "seeing that they have their Bible and—perhaps too, Mill's Political Economy!" This proves in the first place that Kingsley often knew better than what he wrote in his "yeasty" frame of mind, while further it shows that John Stuart Mill had, as we observed in a previous chapter, already drifted far away from the orthodox principles instilled into him by his father. 1) Unto this Last, p. 7. London, 1907. 2) Alton Locke, p. 110. London, 1923. 3) Md., p. 228. 54 Scotch preacher takes up this standpoint: if England finds that her national existence, as is constantly re-iterated by the mill-owner and the merchant of his day, really depends on the question of selling her manufactured cotton a farthing an ell cheaper than any other people, he thinks it would be much better to submit to the inevitable, and discontinue the business, rather than suffer her inhabitants "to fill (their) lungs with cotton-fuzz, (their) hearts with copperasfumes, with rage and mutiny." This is the humanitarian view of a man who conskiers the conditions of life and the happiness of the people to be of infinitely greater importance than the material greatness and power of the state and the interests of its industries. The "condition-of-England" —the phrase, like so many others current in those days, flowed from his pen—had proved to him that instead of being linked up inseparably, the interests of the State and those of Society may lie in diametrically opposite directJons, which he expresses by stating that notwithstanding the fact that "cotton-cloth is already twopence a yard or lower, ... bare backs were never more numerous among us." This happy observation throws a vivid light on the fact that social interests were entirely sacrificed to national in his days. On the page where we find the above observation, Carlyle refers to England's foreign competitors as follows: "The Continental people, it would seem, are "importing our machinery, beginning to spin cotton and manufacture for themselves, to cut us out of this market and then out of that"." This growing competition of foreigners appears to have filled the minds of many business peoplé with uneasiness as to England's industrial supremacy. Other nations were gradually beginning to imitate her in her manufactures, by importing machinery bought from her, and inducing skilied labour to come with those machines. Engels, prognosticating upon "the chances of the English bourgeois" in 1844, said: "German manufacture is now making great efforts, and that of America has developed with great strides." He further gives it as his opinion that in twenty years' time English manufactures will be vanquished, instancing as a proof of what is bound to come the fact of a daring American speculator who sent a shipment of cotton goods to England, where they were sold for re-exportation. McCulloch, on the other hand,—"the favourite 56 economist of the bourgeois", as Engels calls him—re-assured the manufacturing interests of his country, by telling them that it would be ludicrous to suppose that the Americans could hope to be able to compete with an old manufacturing country like England, and that in his opinion she would easily be able to keep the start she had already gained.1 Wherever the truth may have lain between the two extreme opinions of the socialist and the orthodox economist, the fact that the question was discussed by many people2 is in itself a sufficiënt proof that the minds of business-men were not easy upon the matter. This is also clearly reflected in some of the novels of the time, especially in Mrs. Gaskell's social novels, and in Kingsley's Alton Locke and Yeast. It appears that the manufacturers constantly used the bugbear of foreign competition as a convenient weapon tö resist the demands of their workmen for higher wages. The labour troubles in Mary Barton—the masters have offered their unemployed men to take them on again at reduced wages, which the latter refuse to accept—arise from the fact that a duplicate order had been sent to one of the Continental manufacturing towns, where there were no restrictions on food3, no taxes on buildings or machinery; in consequence of this Manchester manufacturers have only been able to secure the big foreign order at greatly reduced quotations, and they maintain that their weavers must share in this reduction. In Mrs. Gaskell's North and South it is this same foreign competition again that causes all the troubles experienced by the millowner John Thornton. This master declares that "what with home and foreign competition, (they) are none of (them) likely to make 1) J. R. McCulloch, Dictionary of Commerce, p. 463. 2) In the Report of the Committee of Manufactures, Commerce and Shipping of 1833 there are numberless statements about the increasing competition of foreigners, from which it would appear that it had begun, as soon as the French wars were over; that it was most severely feit by the shipping trade; that in industry it was chiefly due to the fact that during the war too much capital had been attracted for a profitable employment in peace time—Thistoire se répète a hundred years after!—; that it was "decidedly growing*' year by year; that, though it had greatly reduced the profits, the latter could still be maintained by greater economy in production and greater exercise of skill and industry; etc. 3) One of the very few allusions in Early Victorian fiction to the burning question of the Corn Laws. 57 above a fair share, and may be thankful if (they) can get that. in an average number of years." It is the Americans again who, as he complains, are getting their yarns so into the general market that their only chance in England is producing them at a lower rate. Evklently the manufacturers themselves were already beginning to f eel the pinch of their own much vaunted competition at that time. Thornton also refers to the early cotton-lords, who could dictate their own terms to their customers, while nowadays, he says, the masters have to stand hat in hand to serve them. It appears from the words used by Higgins, one of the strike leaders—he calls the master's argument about the state of the trade a piece of their humbug—that the operatives do not believe in the truth of his argument, but simply consider it as a pretext to keep down their wages. It would of course be easy for the mill-owners to show the necessity of their policy by opening their books, but, as Mrs. Qaskell repeatedly points out, their strongly developed sense of individualism, their dour obstinacy—Higgins calls Thornton "the oud bulldog"—their impatience of all restraint, resulting from their economie faith in the laissez-faire system, all these qualities prevent them from taking this simple course. When the heroine of the novel asks Thornton why he offers no explanation of the real state of affairs to the strikers, to convince them of their wrong, he only replies: "Do you give your servants reasons for your expenditure or your economy in the use of your own money? We, the owners of capital, have a right to choose what we will do with it." 1 From what we read nowadays about the new struggle of the labouring classes to obtain control over the management of private concerns, we are, however, forced to the conclusion that there may be weightier reasons for the owner of a business to refuse to open his books than the rather puerile pig-headedness of the Thorntons and Carsons of a hundred years ago. Having shown by some instances what the attitude of novelists was towards competition among business people, we shall now speak of another kind of competition, not among the masters, but among the workmen themselves. 1) North and South, p. 114. 58 Political economists claimed unfettered freedom of action, not only for the merchant and the manufacturer, but also for the mill operative, who, having a "commodity" to sell, ought equally to be left free to sell it in the dearest market. According to the humanitarian point of view, which was no doubt to a great extent correct, this freedom was a very doubtful asset for the labouring classes. Engels said of it: "Fine freedom, where the proletarian, has no other choice than that of either accepting the conditions which the bourgeoisie offer him, or of starving, or of freezing to death, or sleeping naked among the beasts of the forest." This competition among the workers themselves had even more distressing consequences in the Early Victorian period than that in trade and industry, which, whatever may have been the apprehensions of far-seeing men, had by no means yet reached the keenness of the present time. In a previous chapter1 we have already briefly described the altered structure of English society, broken up by the industrial revolution from local units governed by the squire and the parson, into masses of disconnected individuals, floating about like loose atoms, people who were free to come and go to any place in the country. As we also pointed out there, the free labour market was indispensable for the industrial interests, and necessitated the final demolition of the Elizabethan system of codified labour, by which hours, wages, and everything else concerning the relation between master and servant had been regulated by laws. Many of such statutory enactments had already fallen into desuetude long before their repeal, so that justices of the peace had for instance entirely abandoned the practice of meddling with the wages to be paid in their district. On the other hand, the practice of "prenticing a boy to a trade" still continued to be frequently followed long after the repeal of the Statute, as many passages in literature show us. The reader will remember how little Oliver Twist was led before the magistrates for the signature of his indenture, by Bumble and Gamp the chimney-sweep. Jacob Faithful and various other young heroes in Captain Marryat's novels are apprenticed either to a river barge, a waterman on the Thames, or a sea-going vessel, before they can serve as sailors in the mercantile marine. 1) Introduction, Chapter II. 59 The Settlement Act of 1662, another relic of the older and more rigkl system of economy, was also doomed to disappear with the advent of the laissez-faire system. One of its chief objects had been to authorize parish authorities to send any strangers settling in the parish home again by force within a period of forty days. If they omitted to do so, the new settlers became chargeable to the new parish, in case they should at any future time be unable to maintain themselves. In agricultural districts these powers were regulariy made use of by the parish authorities to prevent strangers from getting what was called "a settlement" in their parish. Landlords and farmers did not wish to increase their parochial poor rates. Many of them, not content to prevent the building of new cottages, went so far as to pull down existing ones, especially when owing to the old Poor Law the pauperization of the rural population caused those rates to rise exorbitantly. Thus we read in Sybil that the town of Marney had become a metropolis of agricultural labour, the proprietors in the neighbourhood having pulled down the cottages on their estates for the last half century.1 The result of this heartless policy was that in rural districts housing conditions became as dreadful as in the great mushroom towns of the North. Walpole cites as an instance of this overcrowding the case of a parish in Dorsetshire, where thirty persons dwelt on an average in each house.2 The question whether a pauper was chargeable to one parish or to another often gave rise to much friction in rural districts, and sometimes even led to litigation. Thus we read in Oliver Twist, how Mr. Bumble is sent up to London one day in connection with "a legal action (which) is a-coming on, about a settlement," to see, if two dying paupers cannot be thrown upon another parish at the Clerkenwell Sessions, as "it would come two pound cheaper to move 'em than to bury 'em." 3 In the rising industrial towns people who could not find a place to live in at home experienced little or no difficulty in finding a settlement, as these towns were constantly in want of fresh labour, 1) Sybil, p. 70. 2) Spencer Walpole, op. cit, vol. IV, pp. 25—30. 3) Oliver Twist, ch. XVIII. According to Leslie Stephen (op. cit) the short clause in the short Act occasioned an average expense of from 300,000 to 350,000/. a year on this kind of litigation. 60 somewhere in Europe, Africa, Asia, or America, doubt it not, you will find cartage; go and seek cartage, and good go with you!" 1 This passage has been closely imitated—like so many others— by Carlyle's great admirer Charles Kingsley.2 Kingsley puts the question of the free labour market thus: "The fellow (i.e. Crawy, a worthless poacher) might have got work, if he had chosen, in Kamschatka or the Cannibal Islands; for the political economists have proved beyond a doubt, that there is work somewhere or other for every one Who chooses to work. But unfortunately, society has neglected to inform him of the Cannibal Island labour market, or to pay his passage thither, when informed thereof The fact that Kingsley adopted a very hostile attitude towards the notion of a free labour market is very natural, when we remember that the Christian Socialists, to whose leaders he belonged at the time he wrote Yeast, based their practical attempts at social improvement solely on the assumption that it was precisely this "alldevouring competition" which lay at the root of all the misery. It is in Alton Locke, which is a long tract rather than a novel, that Kingsley revealed to the English public the horrors of competitive industrialism, as it floui ished unchecked particularly in the tailoring trade.3 As Crossthwaite the Chartist tailor says to his friends, when they have all been dismissed: "Combination among ourselves is the only chance." Curiously enough, however, the author does not pursue his propaganda, by making the dismissed tailors found a Tailors' Association, but contents himself to describe how they feil into the hands of Jemmy Downes and other sweaters. Under the influence chiefly of Ludlow, another of the leaders of the movement, who had been educated in France, and had had many opportunities of studying the Working Men's Associations there,4 the practical experiments of the English Christian Socialists took the form of societies for co-operative production, whose object was of course to render the workers independent of the capitalist masters, 1) Chartism. Collected Works, vol. IX, p. 21. 2) In the first eight chapters of Yeast alone there are at least eleven passages that are a distinct echo of some saying of the "favourite prophet", viz., on pp. 12, 47, 55, 76, 78, 81, 85, 104, 112. London, Everyman's Library. 3) Kingsley had been induced to treat the same subject before in his pamphlet Cheap Clothes and Nasty", after the publication of two letters in the Morning Chronicle on the sweating system, written by Mayhew. 4) C. E. Raven, Christian Socialism, p. 146. London, 1920. 64 she was At Home ever so many nights in a season, she could not am.'ounce more widely and unmistakably than Mr. Merdle did that he was never at home." The poor man is instantly finished as soon as he catches sight of his butler, a splendid retainer, who feels a deep contempt for such a master, who is not a gentleman. At dinners Mr. Merdle sits stupidly pushing a spoon up his sleeve, or clumsily hiding his hands in the coat cuffs, or again staring stupidly down at the pattern of the floor carpet, while after dinner he wanders lumpishly about his own drawing-rooms. The same features in a rising businessman's character are emphasized by Mrs. Gaskell, when she draws the picture of John Thornton, the hero of North and South. She describes him to us as "a great rough fellow, with not a grace or refinement about him," who "feels more awkward and self-conscious in every limb than ever before," when he first meets Miss Hale, the heroine of the story. There is, however, a considerable improvement in Mrs. Gaskell's picture of this representative of the new middle classes: he wishes to educate himself, and for this purpose he takes lessons with Miss Hale's father in classical literature, though his mother does not see the use of it, "the classics being very desirable for people who have leisure, but Milton (i.e. Manchester) men ought to have their powers and thoughts absorbed in the work of to-day." Hers is the general opinion prevalent in Milton, which is expressed by Mrs. Gaskell as follows: "According to the prevalent and apparently well-founded notion of Milton, to make a lad a good tradesman, he must be caught young, and acclimated to the life of the mill, or office, or warehouse ... So most of the manufacturers placed their sons in sucking situations at fourteen or fifteen years of age, unsparingly cutting away all off-shoots' in the direction of literature or high mental cultivation, in hopes of throwing the whole strength and vigour of the plant into commerce."1 It is this same sentiment which is expressed by Ure, the great champion of the much abused manufacturing industry in Early Victorian times, in the opening chapter of his well-known Philosophy of English Manufactures. Only "Grandees," he says, "as the spoiled children of the state, ... may be allowed freely to waste their early years in the pastime of scanning Greek and Roman metres 1) North and South, p. 64. j. 74 A similar attitude towards science and arts in trading circles is manifested by the advice young Cobden, later on the presiding genius of the Anti-Corn Law League, received from his uncle on entering the latter's warehouse: this uncle warned the lad that his passion for study would likely prove a great obstacle for success in commercial life.1 1) Encyclopaedia Britannica; Cobden. 75 CHAPTER VI. Landed Property and Capital* In the preceding chapter we mentioned the fact that carriages were considered an indispensable appendage of the aristrocracy in Early Victorian times. There was, however, something of still greater significance in this respect, viz., the possession of landed property. Such property must naturally always be a great source of political and social power in an agricultural country such as England had been up to the end of the eighteenth century. This power had still been considerably enlarged in England owing to the absence of a central administrative form of government. The administration of the country had been entirely left in the hands of the country gentry. As a nineteenth century writer observes, "the English parish, with its squire, its parson, its lawyer, and its labouring population, was a miniature of the British constitution in general,"1 and that this state of affairs continued far down into the nineteenth century, long after the Reformed Parliament had been elected, is evident from the great number of Early Victorian novels in which at least the squire and the parson, surrounded by tenants and labourers, play the first róle. The result of this state of affairs was that the landowners considered themselves to a certain extent as the only people having a right to live in the country, and only suffered other classes to do so as an act of kindness. Thus we read in Popanilta that the "Aboriginal Inhabitant", as the landed proprietor is called there, "insisted that it was the common law of the land that all the islanders should purchase their corn only of him ... and that if they did not approve of the arrangement, they and their fathers should not have settled upon his island."2 This sounds like Defoe's theory 1) Leslie Stephen, The English Utilitarians, vol. I, p. 30. 2) Benjamin Disraeli, Novels and Tales, vol. IV, p. 410. 76 as put forward in his book The Original Power of the People of England, which was that the freeholders might give notice to quit to the rest of the population.1 The ownership of land was therefore the securest way to give new families a firm footing among the country gentry and nobility. The more English trade expanded in the eighteenth century, the greater the scramble for land became among the wealthy business people. This appears clearly from a passage in Sybil, where Disraeli mentions various groups of these eighteenth century merchants that had successively grown rich before the advent of the Industrial Revolution, and observes how all these "creators of wealth", each in turn aspiring to be "large-acred", were gradually absorbed by the landed interests. As such successive creators of wealth he mentions first the Turkey merchant2—still surviving in Early Victorian literature in the grand personage of John Brough in Thackeray's story of Samuel Titmarsh—; followed by the West Indian planter, who is still much in evidence in Marryat's novels; then by the Indian Nabob—a favourite character in some of Thackeray's works,3 whose preference for this species is probably due to his own Indian origin—; and finally by the loan-monger in the time of the American war, who was succeeded by a new class of loan-mongers that sprang into existence during the reconstruction of Europe after Waterloo and Vienna, and of which we find various representatives in literature.4 1) Cited by Stephen, The English Utilitarians, vol. I, p. 55. The author refers in this connection to the famous words spoken by the Duke of Newcastle, when the Reform Bill was under discussion in the House of Lords: "May I not do what I like with my own?" The question is even echoed in literature by Kingsley (Yeast, p. 112). Defoe wrote: "The Freeholders are the proper Owners of the country: It is their own, and the other inhabitants are but sojourners, like Lodgers in a house, and ought to be subject to such laws as the Freeholders impose upon them, or else they must remove; because the Freeholders having a Right to the Land, the other have no Right to live there but upon sufferance." The Original Power of the Collective Body of the People of England, Examined and Asserted by Daniël Defoe. London. 2) No doubt Disraeli might have gone further back with his enumeration. Sir Josuah Child spoke of merchants who would not find it "so easie to make (their sons) Country-Gentlemen, as now it is, when Land sells at thirty of fourty years Purchase," if the rate of interest on their capital were reduced. A new Discourse of Trade, p. 24. London, 1693. 3) We mention Tuggeridge in Cox's Diary, and Rigby in Barry Lyndon, who made his fortune under Clive. 4) See p. 136. 77 Though not perhaps quite falling wtthin the scope of this book, we wish to say a few words here about the state of English agriculture after the French wars, in the first place because it was deeply affected by the land hunger of the new rich, and further because Early Victorian novelists like Disraeli, Dickens, and Kingsley repeatedly treat the subject in their works. The deplorable condition into which English agriculture had gradually tallen, and which had almost reduced every agricultural labourer to a pauper, was due to a variety of causes. Foremost among these stands the revival of the Elizabethan practice of passing socalled Enclosure Acts, for the purpose of substituting for the "open field" system, or common ownership of the ground that of privatelyowned farms.1 This passing of Enclosure Acts had continued all through the second half of the eighteenth century. Between 1760 -and 1797 no fewer than 1539 had been placed on the Statute book, dealing with nearly three million acres of land. The object of these enactments was to increase the production of foodstuffs, which had gradually become utterly inadequate for the rapidly increasing population, so that instead of a wheat-exporting country, as England had been up till the year 1766, it became a corn-importing country.2 This change was entirely due to the unprecedentedly rapid increase in the population, which continued at such a rate that in spite of numerous improvements in methods, and the consequent increase of production, agriculture utterly failed to meet the vast demand for cereals. This state of affairs, which had caused much uneasiness to British economists and statesmen, also partly explains the great interest excited by the Corn Laws during the Early Victqrian period, an interest which is, however, as we have observed, scarcely reflected in literature, if we except the poetry of Ebenezer Elliot. The consequence of the Enclosure Acts that concerns us most is the fact they had led to the all but complete extinction of the small holders, many of whom could not pay the considerable legal and other expenses—fencing in their allotments, etc.—attendant upon enclosing the common fields. They consequently had to sell their 1) H. O. Meredith, Outlines of the Economie History of England, p. 254. London, Pitman. 2) McCulloch, Dictionary of Commerce, p. 414. 78 properties to large Iandowners, especially when after the French wars there came a time of great depression, simiiar to that agriculture is passing through now, and rendering it difficult for the small man to keep his head above water1. This precarious state of affairs brought a class of men into the field who particularly in those times were constantly on the look-out for people in straitened circumstances who could offer some substan tial security; we mean the money-lenders or usurers, who are ubiquitous in Early Victorian fiction, and of whom we shall have to say a great deal more in another chapter. They found a wide scope for their activities in rural districts with a rapidly sinking class of free farmers. When the high corn prices of Napoleonic times—-readers of \ohn Halifax remember the bread riots of 1812— began to fall after the peace of 1815, the resulting depression completed the work of destruction of the small holders begun by the Enekwures. How money-lenders swooped down upon their prey is described by Charles Reade in It is never too late to mend, where John Meadows, a rich corn factor8 and land surveyor, steps into the village public-house one morning, "to see what farmers wanted to borrow a little money, under the rose, and would pawn their wheat ricks and pay twenty per cent., for that overrated merchandise (Le. money)." He quarrels with his rival Isaac Levi, who also lends money, "when the security is good." Reade describes the struggles of farmer Fielding, who borrows money at ten per cent., on a two months' acceptance, making a rate of sixty per cent. per annum. That this percentage charged for a loan is not so wide off the mark is proved by facts like those mentioned by Sir Gilbert Parker, who tells. of an Irish farmer borrowing a small sum at a bank, and having to pay ia all a rate of about forty per cent.8 A third factor tending to the disappearance of Yeomen and small freeholders was the circumstance that they were mostly too ignorant 1) Peacock tells us in Crotchet Castte of a hard-hearted landed proprietor, Sir Simon Steeltrap, who had "enclosed commons and woodlands" (p. 125). 2) Corn factors, were people who. generally enjoyed a bad reputation— ■ McCulloch, op. cit., p. 412—which is evident from literature as well: Abel Fletcher's mill is attacked by the mob believing that he causes the price of bread to rise by his policy. (John Halifax, vol. I, ch. VII) 3) Sir Gilbert Parker, The Land, the People, and the State, p. 138. London, 1910. 79 to keep abreast of the scientific progress agriculture was then making, manifesting itself in erop rotation, hnproved implements and machinery, land drainage, and other changes. It is also evident that, even if the small holder was aware of the importance of all science could teach him, he lacked the necessary capital to introducé the new principles on his small farm, and therefore must needs plod on along the old ruts, till bankruptcy or a tempting offer from some rich neighbour put an end to his existence as an independent Yeoman. He found himself in the same position as the shopkeeper Solomon Gill in Dombey and Son: times had changed and the old class could not keep abreast of them, with the result that they were swallowed up by the current of modern progress. All thèse circumstances, extinguishing the small holders, brought in their place the nineteenth century large tenant farmers, who held their land on a long lease from "large-acred" landowners, like Lord Minchampstead, who had half a dozen estates in as many counties, and had "added house to house, and field to field," thus rounding off his estates in all directions.1 Sometimes the small farmer tenaciously held out against the attempts of his neighbour to drive him off his plot of ground, and fought to the last with great desperation, as in the case of old farmer Ayliff in Warren's novel Now and Then. The difference between the methods of the new landlords and the old manner of farming is best illustrated in literature by Charles Kingsley, who is perhaps the novelist of the period who knew the conditions of agricultural districts most inthnately, from having lived and worked so long in the rural parish of Eversley. In Yeast he compares the methods of an old-fashioned Whig, the "ignorant and do-nothing" Squire Lavington, with the manner in which the newmade Lord Minohampstead manages his property. On Squire Lavington's estate there are miles of heather and snipe-bog and moors, only producing game and timber. Lord Minchampstead on the other hand exterminated every hare and pheasant on his estate; broke up all the commons,—this is another reference in Early Victorian fiction to the above-mentioned Enclosure Acts;—used steam-engines on his farms; in short, ran his estate on commercial 1) Yeast, p. 85 80 time when a London pamphleteer wrote that "they (were) not so numerous as the Protestants in France, and yet the French King effectually clear'd the Nation of them at once, and we don't find he misses them at home." 1 Charles Kingsley, who as a Churchman must have observed these things with envious eyes, explains the great róle played by Dissent in commerce and industry in the following spiteful manner.2 After stating that frantic Mammon-hunting has been for the last fifty years the peculiar pursuit of Quakers, Dissenters, and religious Churchmen, he goes on to say: "I don't complain of them, though; Puritanism has interdicted to them all art, all excitement, all amusement— except money-making. It is their dernier ressort, poor souls!" That money^naking i.e., a commercial career, was their dernier, or rather their only ressort, is quite true, as we shall see, but in quite a different respect from that stated by Kingsley in his strong dislike of the Puritans. The truth was that Dissenting families were compelled by social circumstances to devote their energies to trade and industry, as both the Church and the üniversities were closed to them, while the landed proprietary governed the country, so that public offices were equally unattainable for them. The natural course of things was therefore that with the rising industrial importance of the country there arose at the same time a powerful and rich Dissenting middle class of merchants and manufacturers. Dibelius expressly states that this new class "gehört im allgemeinen nicht zur Staatskirche," and he points in this connection to the significant fact that of the six partners who originally owned the famous New Lanark Mills in Scotland, three were Quakers.3 This Dissent, however, which George Eliot describes as being of a quiescent,well-to-do kind, was greatly altered in its character by the advent of coalpits and factories, which infused into the chapels and conventicles large quantities of new blood coming from the lower and lowest ranks of life, and which was chiefly responsible for the above-named rapid growth in Early Victorian times. When to the above facts of actual life we add the traditional 1) The Shortest Way with the Dissenters etc. London, 1702. 2) Yeast, p. 71. 3} W. Dibelius, Charles Dickens, p. 2. 87 impopularity of Dissent in fiction, down to at least the middle of last century,1 we are not surprised to find that novelists wishing to draw an unfavourable portrait of a business-man, never forgot to add the stock feature of Dissent to the other unpleasant traits of his picture. This use or perhaps we had better say abuse made of Dissent, is nowhere better illustrated than in the linen-draper Tag-rag,whom we have already mentioned in this chapter. Samuel Warren, to whose true blue political opinions we have likewise referred, was not content to show us Mr. Tag-rag's religious opinions, contrasting them with his mean conduct in private life as well as in his business dealings, but he also made him a "Churchrate martyr," which afforded him an opportunity to attack a Dissenting movement against the payment of Church rates for the upkeep of the buildings of the Anglican Church. Mr. Tag-rag determined to refuse to pay the sum of twopence halfpenny due in respect of this rate, and when he was consequently taken into custody, hjs languishing business suddenly revived owing to its owner's popularity. Samuel Warren betrays the same hostile spirit towards Dissent in representing the mean and caddish hero of his novel Ten Thousand a Year, who has never shown any religious tendencies Or sympathies in his life, as making petitions in Parliament "about Dissenters and the 39 articles of the Established Church, etc." 2 Further there are in the same story the hateful portraits of two Dissenting ministers, the 'Reverend' Dismal Horror, and the 'Reverend' Smirk Mudflkit We have said just now that the hostile attitude of literature towards Dissent and its ministers was persisted in till about the middle of the century. In Samuel Titmarsh Thackeray draws a portrait of the unsympathetic Grimes Wapshot; Dickens has left us the inhnitable 'shepherd', Mr. Stivvings, and Mr. Chadband; Charles Kingsley treats them rather ungenerously in his pictures of Mr. Bowyer, Mr. Wigginton, and Mr. Blaraway, in Alton Locke and Yeast. In Shirley Charlotte Brontë drew the hateful picture of Moses Barraclough, while in the same novel we read of a leader of the Non-Conformists that on being pushed into a ditch, "he drank more 1) Dicey, op. cit, p. 328. 2) Vol. III, p. 66. 88 water in that afternoon, than he harj swallowed for a twelvemonth before." 1 Mrs. Gaskell, whose husband was a Unitarian minister himself, shows a better appreciation of Dissent in the person of Mr. Hale, who leaves the Church on account of his religious scruples, while finally George Eliot drew a sympathetic portrait of a Dissenting preacher in the person of Mr. Rufus Lyon, in whom the usual unctuous, oily hypocrisy of the old literary type is replaced by verbose, argumentative speeohifying of a very harmiess kind, coupled with a brave and noble heart. But Mr. Lyon did not make his appearance in English literature until 1866, thereby affording another proof of the long life literary types often have, and of the great length of time it takes to eradicate prejudices in literature. We have just now referred to the curious fact about the composition of the firm owning the New Lanark Mills commented upon by Dibelius. There is another equally siginificant fact to be observed in the manner in which this firm was reconstructed in the year 1813. The three partners in the business then were the socialist Robert Owen, the Quaker William Allen, and Jeremy Bentham, the incarnation of Utilitarian rationalism.2 The combination of these three men illustrates the fact that the domain of trade and industry was largely shared in those days by two classes of people whose religious opinions differed so widely as to be entirely irreconcilable: the majority of the new bourgeoisie were liberals, not only in politics, but also in religion, whioh means that as a general body they were anti-ecclesiastical. Bentham aimed at laicizing education;» Greg, a late disciple of his school, regrets that the spread of sound education among the working classes "has been retarded by our miserable sectarian animosities (and that so) little has been done to teach them (the) elementary economie laws." James Mill, though licensed as a preacher in the Scottish Church, never followed the profession, "having satisfied himself that he could never believe the doctrines of that, or any other Church," as his son tells us,4 1) Shirley, p. 333. London, 1914. 2) Encyclopaedia Britannica: Robert Owen. 3) In his book Church of Englandism and its Catechism Examined (London 1817) he tried to prove that with the Church Catechism "at the very first dawn of the reasoning faculty" young England is taught bad grammar, bad logic, marters depravating his intellectual faculties, and marters degrading his morals. Preface, pp. XXIX—XXXIII. 4) Autobiography by J. S. Mill, p. 3. 89 while this son himself boasts that he was "one of the very few examples in this country, of one who has, not thrown off religious belief, but never had it."1 John Owen, the founder of Owen's College at Manchester, stipulated that no religious test should ever be applied, neither for the students, nor for the teachers. Lord Marney, the utilitarian landowner in Disraeli's Sybil, shows a decidedly hostile attitude towards religion: he wants an easy-going clergyman of the type of Mr. Slimsey on his estate, who does not care much for his pastoral duties, and the author calls Marney anti-ecclesiastic. On a novelist like Kingsley this anti-religious character of a large section of the business community cannot have failed to have had some influence at least in determining his attitude towards merchants, manufacturers and economists. That the minister of the Established Church was not above such influences is evident from the malicious pictures of Dissenters and Missionaries he drew in Alton Locke, as well as from his prejudiced portraits of Irishmen, and from his hostile attitude towards the Jews, "Messrs. Aaron Levi and the rest of that class," as he contemptuously denotes them.2 This mention of the Jews reminds us of the fact that here we have to do with business-men who were also generally looked upon with a prejudiced eye by Early Victorian novelists. This prejudice was due to racial rather than religious causes. Though Jewish business people abound in the literature of that time, it is hardly possible to cite one instance of a portrait drawn in a fair spirit. The principal line of business Jews are represented to pursue is money-lending, a pursuit which had tradition of many centuries' standing, dating back to the Middle Ages, as readers of Ivanhoe remember. We note the names of Mordecai Gripe, Mephibosheth, Maharshalab Hash-Baz and Israël Fang (Ten Thousand a Year); Levison (Henrietta Tempte); Moses Brown (The Disowned). Another favourite Jewish profession that was deemed still more disreputable was that of Sheriffs officer and keeper of a spunging house. Of this class literature shows us specimens in the persons of Nabb (The Fatal Boots), Solomon Jacobs (Sketches by Boz); Bendigo (Barry Lyndon) and Aminadab (Samuel Titmarsh). 1) J. S. Mill, op. cit, p. 43. 2) Alton Locke, p. 108. 90 must have been given very injudiciously for it to exceed to such an extent the present market value of the property, or, if this had dropped so much in value after being mortgaged, a foreclosure should have been effected long before, and at any rate it should not be put off any longer on the clerlr/s plea about the great loss to be sustained. We might further point to the fact that a foreclosure, like most legal proceedings, takes some considerable time, and would therefore not be a suitable method to secure cash "within a few days." Another expediënt decided upon by Mr. Dudley to get ready money is to sell all his shares in a certain Company, to which course his clerk objects that if he sells out now he will lose heavily on them, whereas, if he waits but six weeks, they will be worth twenty times the purchase price. Though in those times news did not spread so fast, and secrets did not leak out so easily as they do now on the Stock Exchange, yet it is hard to believe that the impending change that is to bring about suoh a tremendous improvement in the position of the Company is not known to other people besides those at Mr. Dudley's office. It may further be asked how it is that Mr. Dudley, instead of selling such a vafuable holding outright, did not use it to obtain a loan on it from his banker. No doubt the disclosure to the banker of the coming boom in the shares would have made him perfectly willing to approve of them as a collateral for such an advance. The rest of the description of the events leading up to the merchant's ruin shows the same degree of impröbability, and suggests many more questions of the same nature as the above. In North and South, by Mrs. Gaskell, we find the same theme of financial embarrassments treated at some length. Here it is the mill-owner Thornton who is involved in them owing to a strike at his works, and a great fall in the prices of raw materials. When combining all the facts stated by the novelist, we find, however, that they ill fit together, which again proves that, as Emerson observes, it requires great courage in a man of letters to handle practical problems, owing to their infinite entanglements.1 1) Thomas Carlyle, Past and Present. Introduction, p. 9. 96